We have presented a simple model to show that trade elasticity is determined by not only consumers’ preferences, but also producers’ comparative advantages in a world where trade is driven by both consumers’ love-of-variety and producers’ comparative advantages. In this model, scale matters in trade elasticity, with smaller countries tending to exhibit a larger one. In addition to tradable intermediate goods, this model also shows that scale is a key factor influencing gains from trade. As a result, smaller countries that are engaged in more international outsourcing activities typically benefit with relatively greater gains from trade after trade liberalization.
JEL Classification: F12; F16; O30.
Trade elasticities, defined by the aggregate response of trade to shocks in trade costs, illustrate the resilience of exporters in the face of a sudden change in trade barriers. In the literature, a change in welfare (away from autarky) depends on only two sufficient statistics: the share of expenditure on domestic goods and trade elasticity 1.{1} Thus, an estimation of trade elasticities is important because it can be used to gauge a country’s welfare performance in the face of an adjustment in trade policy.
In the model of monopolistic competition with a representative firm, trade elasticity is determined by consumers' preferences 2, 3, 4. In this type of model where all differentiated producers export (no selection effects), trade elasticity equals the elasticity of substitution (σ) minus one, denoted as σ-1. However, in the recent decades, a new strand in the literature specifies heterogeneous firms in terms of productivity. In particular, the Pareto distribution has become a good approximation for the distribution of firms’ productivities 5, 6, as is the Fréchet distribution 7, 8. These distributions are characterized by a share parameter, θ, which measures the degree of firm heterogeneity. When firms are heterogeneous such that only relatively high productive firms export (selection effects), Eaton and Kortum 8 and Chaney 9 show that trade elasticity is replaced by the share parameter θ when the selection effect arises. The result is striking, because the impact of the consumers’ preferences on trade elasticities disappears, and the impact is completely replaced by a parameter on the supply side of the economy.
The above models only address the trade of final goods. As an exception, Alvarez and Lucas 10 present a variation of the Eaton-Kortum model 8 in which each country produces one final good and a continuum of intermediate goods. Each country symmetrically aggregates the tradable intermediate goods via a Spence-Dixit-Stiglitz aggregate and then uses the aggregate intermediate goods to produce one variety of a final good exclusively for its own consumption. In their model, only intermediate goods are tradable while final goods are not.
In real practice, in contrast to the above literature, world trade is mixed with not only final goods but also intermediate goods. In order to maximize profits, final goods producers search for the lowest cost of intermediate goods suppliers by sourcing globally in order to minimize their general production cost 11, 12. Considering the fact that the number of intermediate-goods suppliers usually outnumbers that of differentiated final-goods providers substantially, it is feasible to argue that the trade of differentiated final-goods are more likely driven by love-of-variety, such that the selection effects are relatively small. In comparison, the trade of intermediate-goods is mainly driven by cost advantages, such that the selection effects are relatively large. To sharpen the contrast, this paper simply presumes that the final goods are of the Armington-type of final-goods (no selection effects), and that the tradable intermediate-goods are of the Eaton and Kortum 8 type of goods (with selection effects).
Global sourcing is also called vertical specialization, offshore production, or international outsourcing 11, 12, 13, 14.{2} Hereafter, we use the term international outsourcing for consistency in this paper. The above researches show that international outsourcing activities are carried out substantially and that the extent to these activities differs across countries.
As international outsourcing has prevailed in recent decades, final goods are being produced in different stages of production in different regions, such that intermediate goods are shipped across borders more than once 15. Since the general price of the final goods already includes the values of all sources of intermediate goods, a country’s trade volume (in gross value) might be exaggerated over its true value-added due to double counting on the tradable intermediate goods. These intermediate goods, that are first shipped abroad as raw materials and then shipped back as ingredients to the final goods, not only bring up the gross trade volume but also “double count” the trade costs for these intermediate goods across national borders more than once. Often, a country imports intermediate goods to produce final goods for exports; meanwhile, the country also exports intermediate goods that are used as inputs by other countries to produce final goods for their exports. As a result, a country’s trade volume is more sensitive to trade costs if the country is engaged in more intermediate-goods trade, since intermediate goods are more exposed to transportation frictions while they are usually shipped back and forth more than once. In this paper, we hence argue that a country’s trade elasticity is affected by some country characteristics, such as its size and the extent to which it is engaged in international outsourcing. Reasonably, smaller countries that are engaged in more intermediate-goods trade should be more sensitive to the trade costs, since relatively more of their trade is exposed to trade barriers. Therefore, we argue that smaller countries, which are engaged in more intermediate-goods trade, should benefit relatively more from trade liberalization than the other countries.
The rest of the paper runs as follows. Section 3 presents a model to address how international outsourcing reshapes trade elasticity. Section 4 calculates country-specific trade elasticity and gains from trade. Section 5 concludes.
To capture how trade costs disproportionately increase when trade is mixed with intermediate and final goods, we revisit Eaton and Kortum’s 8 model by adding the Armington-type of final goods. In this way, we address how consumers’ love of variety and firms’ comparative advantage might be matched in strength when determining trade volume.
Consider a world of countries, mixed with Armington-type 2 final goods and Eaton-Kortum-type 7 intermediate goods. Country
produces one variety of differentiated final good
and an array of intermediate goods
, for which the common input is labor. Individuals have identical constant elasticity of substitution (CES) preferences on the final goods, and the elasticity of substitution is
. A representative household in country
maximizes her utility:
![]() | (1) |
where is country
’s consumption of the goods from country
. Trade incurs an iceberg transportation cost as
and
,
.
It is widely known that a country’s domestic business services are generally embedded in its manufacturing exports 15. Hence, in this paper, the production of any variety of a final good takes the Cobb-Douglas form and requires a combination of headquarter services and a bundle of intermediate goods:
![]() | (2) |
where is productivity shifter,
denotes headquarter services that are not tradable, and
is the share of tradable intermediate goods in output of the final good production. The tradable intermediate goods are not for direct consumption, but instead are used as inputs in the production of final goods. In a way similar to Eaton and Kortum 7, the bundle of intermediate goods is aggregated by a Cobb-Douglas function across the continuum varieties of intermediate goods:
![]() | (3) |
which Caliendo and Parro 16 refer to as the composite intermediate good aggregate.
2.2. The Intermediate GoodsThe intermediate goods are Eaton-Kortum-type continuum goods . An intermediate good producer in country
draws its productivity
from a Fréchet distribution
, where
denotes the technology of country
that represents the absolute advantage of the country. Firms in a country, that is endowed with a higher level of technology, tend to have a greater possibility of drawing a more efficient productivity. The parameter
reflects the dispersion of productivities in the continuum of goods so that it governs comparative advantages within this continuum.
In (3), the price distribution of the intermediate-goods is then given by in country
where
and
8. Here,
denotes the unit labor cost, the wage in country
. With the Cobb-Douglas preferences, the aggregate price of the intermediate good bundle is given by
in country
, where
is the Euler’s constant.
Implied in (2), the unit cost of producing the final good in country is
and the unit price is then given by
, where
. Here, the labor requirement for producing the headquarter service is a fixed sunk cost
, so that the total cost of producing the final-good is
.
The total output of the final good in country is
. Supposed the number of countries in the Armington world is substantially large, such that the elasticity of demand for each differentiated final good equals the elasticity of substitution as shown in (1). Then, the total output of the final good in country
can be rewritten as
, where
. Here,
denotes the total income of country
.
In monopolistic competition, the total labor force devoted to final good production is the sum of the fixed sunk cost and the headquarter services as , where
.{3} The remaining labor of the country is then devoted to producing the intermediate goods
, which represents the total output of the intermediate goods produced by country
. Hence, the labor market equilibrium in the intermediate good sector requires
![]() |
where represents country
’s total employment engaged in intermediate-goods production.{4} As the production of the intermediate goods is under perfect competition, we have
. Country
’s total output of the intermediate goods can now be rewritten as
![]() | (4) |
where represents the total income of country
.
Following Eaton and Kortum’s 7 model, we use to denote the accumulated technology of country
that represents the absolute advantage of that country, in which
denotes the research productivity of researchers and
is country i’s research intensity. Researchers produce patents specific to the intermediate goods and acquire a fixed share of output as profits as
in their general equilibrium.{5} Borrowing from their results, we then have
![]() | (5) |
Combining (4) and (5), we obtain an output-to-income ratio as
![]() | (6) |
Equation (6) implies that a high research intensity country tends to be engaged in more intermediate-goods production and less final-goods production. The probability that country is the cheapest source of a particular intermediate-goods exporter to country
is
, which also represents the fraction of the intermediate goods that country
buys from country
. Hence, country
’s total spending on the intermediate-goods from country
is as
![]() | (7) |
where is country
’s price parameter of intermediate-goods. In (7), the total output of the intermediate goods in country
is given as
, where
. Then, we get
. Upon plugging the above expression into (7), with
, we obtain the gravity equation of the intermediate goods:
![]() | (8) |
The budget constraint for country n’s total spending on the final goods is as
![]() | (9) |
where and
denotes price of the final good
in country
. Solve (1) with the constraint in (9) to get the imports of good
by country
:
![]() | (10) |
where is the price index of final goods and
,
. In (9) and (10), we obtain
to represent the contribution of country
’s final-good on country n’s spending.
Demand equals supply in the final good sector in equilibrium. With (10), we get
![]() | (11) |
where . We can rewrite (11) to get
. Plugging the above relation into (10), we obtain the exports of the final-good from country
to country
:
![]() | (12) |
In equilibrium, the total sales of the intermediate goods are equal to their total output, with equation (7), so we have . Note that, in general equilibrium, Eaton and Kortum 7 show that
,
, when population growth rates are the same across countries. Since labor supply is inelastic supply in each country in this model, we take this result as given. Then, if being under free trade, with equation (5), we return to the Eaton and Kortum’s 7 model:
![]() | (13) |
As is well known, in addition to final-good trade, the strategy of international outsourcing is popularly employed by the world’s most productive firms, such as Apple, Microsoft, Sony, Nokia, Hewlett-Packard, and many others.{6} These firms contract with specialized Original Equipment Manufacturing (OEM) or Electronics Manufacturing Service (EMS) providers that offer customized manufacturing services, such as Foxconn. International outsourcing also prevails in labor-intensive products, such as athletic and casual footwear.{7} To cope with real practices, therefore, we instead consider that a country’s total exports consist of exports of both final and intermediate goods in the following.
Alvarez and Lucas 10 presume that final goods are not tradable in their model. Instead, we allow the final goods to be tradable, inasmuch as the intermediate goods are also tradable. In this current model, the final goods are the Armington-type goods. The Armington type of final goods generates no extensive margin, such that the net impact of consumers’ preferences on trade elasticity should not be completely cancelled out.
With (8) and (12), the total exports from country to
is then given by
![]() | (14) |
Define to denote the ratio of intermediate to final goods that are exported from country
to country
, and which can be rewritten as
![]() | (15) |
where represents the share of country
in world income and also represents country
’s share of its own output.{9}
Hummels, Ishii, and Yi 14 define the vertical specialization/international outsourcing of a country as the share of the country’s usage of imported inputs in producing final-goods. Per their definition, we define the share of international outsourcing for a country as a whole as
, where
is the total imports of intermediate inputs in country
from the other countries abroad. We further define
to represents the share of international outsourcing of country
that is contributed by country
. Then, in aggregate, we have
.
As implied in (2), the total demand for the intermediate goods of country is as
. Recall in (7), that we have
. Putting them together, the share of international outsourcing of country
that is contributed by country
is
![]() | (16) |
For a country as a whole, as defined above, the share of international outsourcing the country engages in is
. From (16), we obtain
![]() | (17) |
where is the probability that country
is the lowesr cost suppliers for any intermediate-goods in the domestic market and which captures the comparative advantages of country
.
Combining (15) and (16), we obtain . Taking the differentiating logarithm of (14) with respect to trade cost in absolute value, we obtain the trade elasticity as
, and this can be expressed as
![]() | (18) |
When there is no intermediate-goods production as , equation (18) returns to the Armington model, and the associate trade elasticity becomes
,
. If a country is substantially small such as
and all tradable goods are intermediate-goods, we then obtain
. This is in line with Costinot and Rodriguez-Clare 17, who introduce tradable intermediate-goods into the Eaton and Kortum 8 model and show that trade elasticity remains constant as
. In the model of Costinot and Rodriguez-Clare 17, the extent to which international outsourcing is conducted is both exogenous and symmetric for all countries. To the contrary, in this current model, as implied in (16), the international outsourcing is endogenous and asymmetric. After all, in real practice, international outsourcing activities that are carried out differ substantially across countries.
As argued above, we presume that there are no selection effects on final-goods producers, but there are selection effects on intermediate-goods producers. Therefore, when world trade is mixed with final goods and intermediate goods, equation (18) shows that trade elasticity is a linear combination of consumers’ preference (governed by elasticity of substitution parameter ) and producers’ comparative advantages (governed by the dispersion-of-productivity parameter
), ranging along
. This is the first implication of this model.
Given , {10} it also implies in (18) that scale matters for a country’s trade elasticity, and that small countries tend to have a larger trade elasticity. As a result, there exists heterogeneity in the growth rates of sales among countries after trade liberalization. Arkolakis 18 argues that trade liberalization benefits relatively more the smaller exporting firms in a market. In comparison to Arkolakis 18, this current model implies that trade liberalization benefits smaller countries, ceteris paribus, relatively more (exports) than larger ones. This is the second implication in this model. We summarize the above two implications on aggregate trade elasticity as below:
Proposition 1. A country’s trade elasticity is determined not only by consumers’ preferences but also producers’ comparative advantages, and smaller countries tend to have larger trade elasticity.
Recall in (10) that and in (2) that
, thus we get
![]() |
We also have and
in (7), which leads to
. Putting them together, we thus obtain
![]() |
where . It is easy then to obtain the real wage from above as:
![]() | (19) |
The change in welfare after open trade in country is defined as the change in real wages, which is the so called gains from trade. Arkolakis et al. 1 define the gains from trade as
, where a denotes autarky and
is the real wage. Per their definition, the change in welfare (free trade vs. autarky) in this model is as
![]() | (20) |
which is determined by both consumer preference () and by firms’ comparative advantages (
) as well.{11} Recall that
in (15), and that
in (18). The gains from trade in (20) can now be further rewritten as
![]() | (21) |
which shows that the gains from trade increase with a country’s size () as well its share of international outsourcing activities (
). We argue that a country’s trade volume will be more sensitive to trade costs if the country is engaged in more international outsourcing activities, since intermediate goods are usually higher exposed to transportation frictions while they are shipped back and forth across national borders more than once.{12} This argument is somehow in line with Costinot and Rodiguez-Clare 17 and Feenstra and Hanson 11 in that welfare improves with international outsourcing.
Equation (21) also implies that scale matters in gains from trade, and that smaller countries tend to benefit with relatively greater gains after trade liberalization. The intuition is simple. Having the Armington-type of final-goods, that trade is purely driven by the love-of-variety, the smaller country trades with the world with a larger share of its output, hence having more gains from trade. This implication corresponds to Proposition 1, which implies that trade liberalization benefits smaller countries, ceteris paribus, relatively more (exports) than larger ones. We use Proposition 2 to summarize the above two implications.
Proposition 2. A smaller country that is engaged in more international outsourcing activities tends to benefit with relatively greater gains from trade after trade liberalization.
We have presented a simple model to show that trade elasticity is determined by not only consumers’ preference but also producers’ comparative advantages, and that smaller countries tend to have larger trade elasticity compared to larger countries. In a world where trade is driven by not only consumers’ love-of-variety, but also producers’ comparative advantages, trade elasticity might be understated if we consider trade pattern as being purely driven by consumers’ love-of-variety preferences on the demand side, while conversely it might be overstated if we consider trade pattern as being entirely driven by producers’ comparative advantages on the supply side.
In addition to international outsourcing, this paper shows that scale matters in both trade elasticity and gains from trade. There is also heterogeneity in the growth rates of exports among countries after trade liberalization. Particularly, smaller countries that are engaged in more international outsourcing activities tend to acquire greater gains from trade after trade liberalization.
The financial support provided by Taiwan’s Ministry of Science and Technology (104-2410-H-002-009-MY2) is gratefully acknowledged.
1. Arkolakis, Arnaud, and Rodiguez-Clare 1 express the change in gains from trade by π-1/ε, where π denotes the share of expenditure on domestic goods and denotes trade elasticity.
2. Using input–output tables from ten OECD and four emerging market countries, they estimate that international outsourcing accounts for 21% of these countries’ exports and increased almost 30% between 1970 and 1990.
3. The share of the fixed sunk cost is . As implied in (2), the share of the headquarter services is as
. In sum, we obtain
.
4. In the Armington world, each country specifies one differentiated final-good.
5. In Eaton and Kortum’s 7 model, an idea in a country is drawn from a Pareto distribution
, and a firm in the country employs the idea to produce a specific intermediate good. The chance if the idea is the best idea that leads to the lowest cost in production and commands a mark-up of at least
in country
is
. The probability of a mark-up of at least m given that the idea is a successful idea in country n is then
, which implies that the markup that is conditional on the idea being the best idea follows a Pareto distribution with a parameter
as
. The net profit share from producing the intermediate good is
, so that the expected share of the profits from the best idea in a market is as
.
6. For example, Apple designed most of the system architectures for the iPod, iPad and iPhone in-house, but simultaneously outsourced more than 99 percent of these consumer electronics’ intermediate inputs to the low-wage Asia-Pacific region 19.
7. For example, the Taiwanese Pou Chen Corporation produces more than 200 million pairs of shoes annually for Nike, Adidas, and New Balance under OEM/ODM contracts 20.
8. With (14), we can rewrite as
. With (6), we get
while (e.g., Eaton and Kortum, 2001), such that
. Alternatively, in real practice, we have
, so that
.
9. Note that in (10), denotes the share of country
’s income spending on country n’s final-good. Therefore, the share of country
’s income spending on its own final-good is given by
. On the other hand,
also represents country
’s share of its output, so that
.
10. For example, see Eaton and Kortum, 8 and Arkolakis 1.
11. In autarky,
12. Nevertheless, in contrast to Feenstra and Hanson’s [11] model, wherein the gains from trade for unskilled workers are conditional on when international outsourcing is sufficiently small, equation (21) implies that international outsourcing is explicitly welfare improving while we presume one type of workers.
[1] | Arkolakis, Costas, Costinot Arnaud, and Andres Rodiguez-Clare, 2012. ‘New Theories, Same Old Gains?’ American Economic Review, 102 (1):94-130. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[2] | Armington, Paul, 1969, ‘A Theory of Demand for Products Distinguished by Place of Production’, International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, XVI (1969), 159-78. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[3] | Krugman, Paul R, 1980. ‘Scale Economies, Product Differentiation, and the Pattern of Trade,’ American Economic Review, 70(5): 950-959. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[4] | Anderson, James E. and Yoto V. Yotov, 2010. ‘The Changing Incidence of Geography,’ American Economic Review, 100(5): 2157-86. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[5] | Axtell, Robert L. 2001. ‘Zipf Distribution of U.S. Firm Sizes,’ Science, 293: 1818-1820. | ||
In article | View Article PubMed | ||
[6] | Luttmer, Erzo G. J., 2007. ‘Selection, Growth, and the Size Distribution of Firms,’ The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122 (3): 1103-1144. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[7] | Eaton, Jonathan and Samuel S. Kortum, 2001. ‘Technology, Trade, and Growth: A Unified Framework,’ European Economic Review, 45: 742-755. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[8] | Eaton, Jonathan and Samuel S. Kortum, 2002. ‘Technology, Geography, and Trade,’ Econometric, 70 (5), 1741-1779. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[9] | Chaney, T, 2008. ‘Distorted Gravity: Heterogeneous Firms, Market Structure, and the Geography of International Trade,’ American Economic Review, 98: 1707-1721. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[10] | Alvarez, Fernando and Robert Lucas, Jr., 2007. ‘General Equilibrium Analysis of the Eaton-Kortum Model of International Trade,’ Journal of Monetary Economics, 54(6): 1726-1768. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[11] | Feenstra, R. C., Hanson, G. H., 1996. ‘Foreign investment, outsourcing and relative wages’, The Political Economics of Trade Policy: Papers in Honor of Jagdish Bhagwati, MIT Press, 89-127. | ||
In article | PubMed | ||
[12] | Antràs, P. and E. Helpman, Global Sourcing, 2004. J. Political Economy 112, 552-80. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[13] | Grossman, Gene and Helpman, Elhanan, 2002. ‘Integration vs. Outsourcing in Industry Equilibrium’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 85-120. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[14] | Hummels, David, Jun Ishii and Kei-Mu Yi , 2001. ‘The nature and growth of vertical specialization in world trade,’ Journal of International Economics, 54 (1): 75-96. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[15] | Koopman, Robert, Zhi Wang, and Shang-Jin Wei. 2014. ‘Tracing Value-Added and Double Counting in Gross Exports’, American Economic Review, 104(2): 459-94. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[16] | Caliendo, Lorenzo and Parro, Fernando, 2015. ‘Estimates of the Trade and Welfare Effects of NAFTA,’ Review of Economic Studies, 82(1): 1-44. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[17] | Costinot Arnaud, and Andres Rodiguez-Clare, 2013. ‘Trade Theory with Numbers: Quantifying the Consequences of Globalization’, Handbook of International Economics, Volume 4, edited by G. Gopinath, E. Helpman, and K. Rogoff. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[18] | Arkolakis, Costas, 2010. ‘Market Penetration Costs and the New Consumers Margin in International Trade,’ Journal of Political Economy, 118(6): 1151-99. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[19] | Einhorn, B., 2007. ‘Apple’s Chinese Supply Lines,’ January 8, 2007, BusinessWeek. | ||
In article | |||
[20] | Lo, Chu-Ping, Su-Ying Hsu, and Shih-Jye Wu, 2014. ‘The role of overseas Chinese-speaking regions in global sourcing,’ China Economic Review, 30: 133-142. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
Published with license by Science and Education Publishing, Copyright © 2018 Lo Chu-Ping
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License. To view a copy of this license, visit
https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/
[1] | Arkolakis, Costas, Costinot Arnaud, and Andres Rodiguez-Clare, 2012. ‘New Theories, Same Old Gains?’ American Economic Review, 102 (1):94-130. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[2] | Armington, Paul, 1969, ‘A Theory of Demand for Products Distinguished by Place of Production’, International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, XVI (1969), 159-78. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[3] | Krugman, Paul R, 1980. ‘Scale Economies, Product Differentiation, and the Pattern of Trade,’ American Economic Review, 70(5): 950-959. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[4] | Anderson, James E. and Yoto V. Yotov, 2010. ‘The Changing Incidence of Geography,’ American Economic Review, 100(5): 2157-86. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[5] | Axtell, Robert L. 2001. ‘Zipf Distribution of U.S. Firm Sizes,’ Science, 293: 1818-1820. | ||
In article | View Article PubMed | ||
[6] | Luttmer, Erzo G. J., 2007. ‘Selection, Growth, and the Size Distribution of Firms,’ The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 122 (3): 1103-1144. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[7] | Eaton, Jonathan and Samuel S. Kortum, 2001. ‘Technology, Trade, and Growth: A Unified Framework,’ European Economic Review, 45: 742-755. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[8] | Eaton, Jonathan and Samuel S. Kortum, 2002. ‘Technology, Geography, and Trade,’ Econometric, 70 (5), 1741-1779. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[9] | Chaney, T, 2008. ‘Distorted Gravity: Heterogeneous Firms, Market Structure, and the Geography of International Trade,’ American Economic Review, 98: 1707-1721. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[10] | Alvarez, Fernando and Robert Lucas, Jr., 2007. ‘General Equilibrium Analysis of the Eaton-Kortum Model of International Trade,’ Journal of Monetary Economics, 54(6): 1726-1768. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[11] | Feenstra, R. C., Hanson, G. H., 1996. ‘Foreign investment, outsourcing and relative wages’, The Political Economics of Trade Policy: Papers in Honor of Jagdish Bhagwati, MIT Press, 89-127. | ||
In article | PubMed | ||
[12] | Antràs, P. and E. Helpman, Global Sourcing, 2004. J. Political Economy 112, 552-80. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[13] | Grossman, Gene and Helpman, Elhanan, 2002. ‘Integration vs. Outsourcing in Industry Equilibrium’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 85-120. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[14] | Hummels, David, Jun Ishii and Kei-Mu Yi , 2001. ‘The nature and growth of vertical specialization in world trade,’ Journal of International Economics, 54 (1): 75-96. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[15] | Koopman, Robert, Zhi Wang, and Shang-Jin Wei. 2014. ‘Tracing Value-Added and Double Counting in Gross Exports’, American Economic Review, 104(2): 459-94. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[16] | Caliendo, Lorenzo and Parro, Fernando, 2015. ‘Estimates of the Trade and Welfare Effects of NAFTA,’ Review of Economic Studies, 82(1): 1-44. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[17] | Costinot Arnaud, and Andres Rodiguez-Clare, 2013. ‘Trade Theory with Numbers: Quantifying the Consequences of Globalization’, Handbook of International Economics, Volume 4, edited by G. Gopinath, E. Helpman, and K. Rogoff. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[18] | Arkolakis, Costas, 2010. ‘Market Penetration Costs and the New Consumers Margin in International Trade,’ Journal of Political Economy, 118(6): 1151-99. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[19] | Einhorn, B., 2007. ‘Apple’s Chinese Supply Lines,’ January 8, 2007, BusinessWeek. | ||
In article | |||
[20] | Lo, Chu-Ping, Su-Ying Hsu, and Shih-Jye Wu, 2014. ‘The role of overseas Chinese-speaking regions in global sourcing,’ China Economic Review, 30: 133-142. | ||
In article | View Article | ||