Article Versions
Export Article
Cite this article
  • Normal Style
  • MLA Style
  • APA Style
  • Chicago Style
Research Article
Open Access Peer-reviewed

Impact of Financial Liberalization on Income Inequality: A PVAR Approach

Chokri Zehri , Hamadi Ben Abid
International Journal of Econometrics and Financial Management. 2019, 7(1), 1-11. DOI: 10.12691/ijefm-7-1-1
Received October 28, 2018; Revised January 04, 2019; Accepted January 22, 2019

Abstract

We estimate a panel vector autoregressive model (PVAR) to study the impact of financial liberalization on income inequality. The analysis is carried out for 162 countries over the period 1980-2015. The results show that capital account liberalization and financial development increase inequality. However, it change according to the category of income countries (low, middle and high-income) and according to the period of study used (before and after 1990). The shocks caused by the indicators of financial liberalization on income inequality are very low but persistent in time.

1. Introduction

Criticism has been leveled at financial liberalization since 1990 (e.g., financial instability, financial crises, banking crises, increased inequalities, etc.) 1, 2. More recent criticism has mentioned the increase in the income inequality for developing countries as well as for developed countries. The rise in income inequality is due to the decline in the quality of institutions and the weakness of pro-worker economic policies, replaced by a neo-liberal model. Other recent issues also weaken workers' rights, which include social protection, the privatization of public services and the deregulation of financial markets. The process of financial liberalization seems to favor these inequalities.

Theoretically, impact of financial liberalization on inequality is ambiguous. Empirically, the relationship is also very mixed. It would be interesting to contribute to this field of research by providing a few novelties. We propose the decomposition of this relationship according to the incomes countries categories and according to the period of study regarded (before and after 1990). We use the method of panel vector autoregression (PVAR) developed by Love and Zicchino 3. PVARs combine the advantages of the traditional Vector Autoregression (VAR) with the advantages of panel-data models.

Our indicators grouping the main components of the process of financial liberalization (capital account liberalization, financial development, and financial globalization). With a panel composed of 162 countries for the period from 1980 to 2015 (Table 1).

The analysis is distributed among countries with low, middle, and high incomes. This distinction may help to validate our results. Intercountry inequality is examined by Summers, Kravis, and Heston 4. They discover that income inequality fell sharply across industrialized countries from 1950 to 1980, declined somewhat for middle-income ones, and rose slightly for low-income nations. Our analysis start with the end of their analysis (1980), the impact sought may differ according to the temporal scale. We divided the analysis into two sub-periods, from 1980 to 1990 and from 1991 to 2015.

The results found in this study are the following:

First, the baseline model, using all panel countries, shows a positive contribution of capital account liberalization and financial development on the rise of inequality. Oppositely, the financial globalization reduces it.

Second, when we do the difference of panels according to the category of income, results are different. The capital account liberalization reduces the income inequality except for the high-income economies. The financial development reduces the income inequality except for the low-income economies. We show an opposite effect is also detected between capital account liberalization and financial development for low and high-income countries.

Third, the first period (from 1980 to 1990) presents more significant results than the second period. Negative impact of capital account liberalization and financial globalization on the rise of inequality is detected.

The paper is organized as follows: The following section presents a literature review on the related financial liberalization and inequality. Third section presents the variables determinants for this relationship. We present after my empirical models, the statistical tests of specifications and the results found. The two last sections interprets these results and gives the necessary conclusions.

2. Literature Review

The analysis of the impact of finance on the inequality has essentially scope on three components: financial liberalization, financial development and globalization. The results of this impact were multiple as well theoretically and empirically 5.

Theoretically, financial liberalization may affect income distribution, first, when it acts against the imperfections of the credit markets for the benefit of poor agents and thus reduces inequalities 6. Second, financial liberalization leads to greater equity in the access to credit that makes the domestic financial market more efficient 7. All these effects however are hardly to be seen in practice. In most cases, financial liberalizations have not been successful. Even if growth may have accelerated, though not in all cases, efficiency has decreased and income distribution has worsened, leading to an increase in inequality.

Empirically results are also diverse; some recent studies (based on cross-country data) report financial liberalization reduces income inequality 8, 9. Some others conclude that financial liberalization increases inequality 10, 11, 12.

We present in the following some works on this relation with different impacts.

Among the recent studies, Furceri and Loungani 11 have used a panel of 150 countries over the period 1970 to 2010. They estimate an equation of inequality univariate autoregressive, with dependent variable the logarithm of the annual variation of Gini coefficient which is explained by a dummy variable which takes 1 in a period of liberalization of the capital account and 0 for other periods and explained by a vector X of control variables. They show that the increase of the liberalization of the capital account has been followed by an increase in the inequalities. However, they found two channels to which this association is limited: the first, the impact of liberalization on inequality is low for the countries with high levels of financial development. The second, this impact is also low in cases where liberalization is not followed by a crisis.

For their recent analysis in 2017, with 224 episodes of liberalization of the capital account, most during the past two decades, the same authors use a regression "kitchen-sink" involving many potential determinants of this relationship. Using an autoregressive equation, which the dependent variable is the growth rate of the inequality measured by the logarithm of the annual variation of Gini coefficient. They find that the capital account liberalization (Chinn-Ito index) leads to a decline in the fair sharing of labor income and which corresponds to an increase of the coefficient of the Gini indicator. Similarly, these adverse effects on the inequality are most apparent when the liberalization is accompanied by a large increase in capital flows, an increase of commercial opening and more extensive technological exchange.

A similar study of LaGarda and al. p12 12 examine the idea according to which the liberalization of the capital account is associated with inequality of income among the emerging economies and developing countries. The authors show several different impacts of capital account liberalization during the movements of "comes and goes" of capital flows. During normal periods (moderate liberalization), they found a positive impact on inequality, then that in a period of increased liberalization of the capital account the inequality deteriorates and called to more active policies.

J. De Haan, R. Pleninger and J.E. Sturm 13 re-examines the impact of the financial liberalization on income inequality using a panel model with fixed effects for a wide sample of countries covering the period 1975-2005, while laying down the analysis on the countries with more of income inequality. The dependent variable is the average over 5 years of Gini coefficents. They also use two indicators of financial liberalization: indicator of Abiad, Detragiache, and Tressel 14 and Chinn-Ito indicator of liberalization of the capital account 15, 16. The authors find that the financial liberalization is associated with an increase in the inequality of income. This increase is mainly the more remarkable among countries with financial systems more developed.

Theoretically, the relationship between liberalization and inequality of income is ambiguous, as suggested Bumann and Lensink 17. These authors have developed a theoritical model comprising several agents investors in relationship with the banking system. Their model suggests that financial liberalization allow an equitable distribution of income for the countries with more depth of the financial systems. Their empirical estimates confirm this hypothesis. More specifically, their estimations suggest that the liberalization of the capital account led to a decline of the inequality of income if the level of financial deepening, measure by private appropriations as a percentage of GDP, exceed 25%.

Other authors are looked on globalization. Jaumotte, and al. 18 use a panel of 51 countries for 23 years from 1981 to 2003. The equation used explains the logarithm of the Gini coefficient by variables of commercial globalization, variables of financial globalization, variables reflecting the technological progress and other variables of controls. The paper presents estimates confirming the higher impact of technological progress on the inequality than that of globalization.

Dabla-Norris and al. 19 found that financial globalization can facilitate an international allocation efficient capital and promotes a better sharing of the risk. At the same time, the increase of capital flows, particularly foreign direct investment and portfolio investment seem to increase the income inequality as well for the developed countries and emerging economies.

3. Liberalization and the Determinants of Income Inequality

The Gini coefficient is often used to measure the inequality; it gives a value of 0 if the total income is also shared in a country, and 100 if a single individual account for the totality of the income. If the Gini coefficient increases, inequality is increasing.

As dependent variable, we use the first difference of the logarithm of Gini coefficients (noted DLGINI). These coefficients are obtained based on households’ gross income from Solt’s 20 Standardized World Income Inequality Database (SWIID, 2016){1}.

In conjunction with the papers previously presented, we use the KAOPEN index to reflect the capital account liberalization. It is a measure of the degree of opening of the capital account of a country. Chinn and Ito initially used this indicator in 2006. KAOPEN is based on information regarding restrictions in the IMF’s Annual Report on Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions (AREAER). This indicator varies between -1.856 (more controlled capital account) to 2.456 (less controlled).

The financial liberalization process has often been correlated with the financial development 21, 22, 23. The variable LF_Dev will represent the financial development. The data of this index is collect from K. Svirydzenka, (2016), the author use a broad multi-dimensional approach to defining financial development follows the matrix of financial system characteristics developed by Čihák and al. 24.

The sharp deepening in financial liberalization represents one of the key implications of globalization. The close relationship between financial liberalization and globalization is not in doubt{2} 25, 26. We use the KOF Index of Globalization (noted GLOBAL) to reflect globalization. This Index measures the economic, social and political dimensions of globalisation.

The three previous variables, KAOPEN, LF_Dev, and GLOBAL will be the main variables of explanatory income inequality in the following empirical models.

The liberalization of capital movements can be a source of volatility - abundant capital inflows, followed by outputs, and vice versa. The criticism of the liberalization are convinced that this volatility is a source of Crisis 27. At the same time, liberalization should, in theory, increase the sources of capital available to borrowers of the country. In practice, the strength of domestic financial institutions may be a crucial factor that determines if this occurs or not.

The impact of the liberalization is more marked when it is followed by a crisis and when the level of development and inclusion of the financial sector is low 13. In order to consider these two elements, we followed the procedure of Furceri and Loungani 11 by constructing two composite indexes: the first noted KAOPENXCRISIS{3} and the second KAOPENXDEV. These two-composite indexes are added to the three previous variables to form an explanatory model of DLGINI.

Income inequalities are also created or exacerbated by the mechanisms of the market. The inequalities of income would be greatly due to the offer and the demand in the employment market. The individual talent and the demand for such capabilities are the main criteria for fixing wages and primary determinants of income levels. The level of education of workers may reflect this aspect. We thus use a variable "School" measuring the School enrollment, primary and secondary (gross).

The technological changes of recent decades have polarized the labor market by promoting the highly skilled workers, to the detriment of those who are very little. The expenditure on research and development go hand in hand with technological progress. This variable (noted RD) will be included in our models. However, its data start only from the year 1996.

The globalization of trade has the effect to polarize incomes: it exerts a growing pressure on low-skilled workers in developed countries to accept a lower compensation, and it encourages remunerating much better workers who are more qualified. The competition between workers and between nations would have greatly contributed to the increase in inequalities between nations and between individuals. The ratio of open trade will be representative of this aspect, it will be noted TRADE.

The variables CRISIS, School, RD and TRADE{4} will be added one by one to our three basic variables KAOPEN, LF_Dev and GLOBAL to form models to explain DLGINI. The description of all these variables are grouped in the Table 2 of appendices{5}. (See also Table 3 for the descriptive statistics and correlation of these variables).

4. Evolution Financial liberalization/income Inequality

It is not obvious to draw the graphs of 162 countries. A graph grouping all the countries can provide information on the overall evolution of these variables but will not be very significant in taking the average of these variables. To do so, We have calculated the average of each indicator for all countries for each year. This has enabled us to obtain a general pace of the average of all countries between 1980 and 2015.

The Graph 1 represents the evolution of the index Gini and of our three indicators of liberalization for the whole panel. It shows an increase in the average of the GINI index up until 2005 and then a gradual decline until 2015. Despite the decline, this index remains high and has never fallen below 0.36 for the entire period.

For our indicators of financial liberalization, we note a generally bottom-up pace of three indicators. This may reflect the continuity of this process of liberalization throughout the period of analysis. It also shows a similarity of the financial information made by these variables.

The Graph 2 represents the evolution of the GINI coefficient for each category of income of countries (low, middle and high income). The pace is very similar between the low-income and middle-income economies, it is a little fluctuating up to 1990, and then up-scaling up to 2005 and then it gradually drops. For the high-income economies, it differs a little. The GINI indicator increases up to 2009, and then declines up to 2015.

In summary, two stylized facts emerge from these graphs. First, an evolution almost similar between the Gini index and financial indicators for a large part of the period of analysis. This similarity is supported also by a great similarity between the evolution of our indicators of financial liberalization. Second, a similar evolution of the Gini index for the low-income and middle-income groups, but a little less for the high-income. The three categories of income present a bottom-up pace just before 1990.

5. Specification of the Models

We use a panel-data vector auto-regression methodology. This technique uses the traditional VAR approach, which treats all the variables in the system as endogenous, with the panel-data approach, which allows for unobserved individual heterogeneity.

The PVAR technique is particularly suitable for our purposes because we seek to model the evolution of a system of our variables of interest - inequality index, financial development, capital account liberalization, and financial globalization (DLGINI, LF_Dev, KAOPEN, and GLOBAL) - in a set of countries which significantly differ along various dimensions such as the development of their financial and economic systems and the level of financial openness. These unobservable country-specific differences are captured with country fixed effects in our model.

The structure of our baseline PVAR model can be written in reduced form as follows:

where Yit is a vector of our variables (DLGINI, LF_Dev, KAOPEN, and GLOBAL) for year "t" and country "i" and modeled as a function of the first-order lags of all variables in the system. The fi and dt terms are country fixed effects and time fixed effects respectively.

The baseline model to estimate brings together all the countries (162 countries) for the period from 1980 to 2015. The second step is to estimate this model according to the three income classes, low-income countries (29), medium income (87), and high income (46). In a third step, we take the change in opinion on the effects of the financial liberalization by splitting the period of analysis into two sub-periods, from 1980 to 1990 and from 1991 to 2015.

We follow the steps of Abrigo and Love (2015), who presented a package of controls on STATA for analysis of the Panel VAR models. Based on the two models of criteria for the selection of Andrews and Lu (2001) (MBIC,and MQIC) and the coefficient of determination overall, the model with a single delay is preferred, since it presents the lowest values of MBIC and MQIC (Table 5){6}.

The augmented Dickey-Fuller and Phillips-Perron tests shows the absence of unit root for our four variables (Table 4). We reject the null hypothesis of the presence of unit root. This observation is also valid for the indicator LF_Dev, at the 5% significance level (the others are valid for 1% significance level).

The non-presence of the unit root has enabled us to move to the study of the causality between our variables. The results of the estimation of the baseline model are presented in Table 6. The models 1 to 6 are composed by our basic variables: DLGINI, KAOPEN, LF_Dev, LGLOBAL and for each model, we add a new explanatory variable of the inequality among the following variables: CRISIS, KAOPENXCRISIS, KAOPENXDEV, LTrade, LSchool and LRD. The Model 6 is a complete baseline model using all the variables cited{7}.

6. Results Interpretations

These models show that capital account liberalization (KAOPEN) has a significant and positive relationship with the variation in income inequality. For all six models capital account liberalization increase income inequality 10, 11. We can explain this result by the fact that financial liberalization can skew the allocation of credit to those who do not need it and ignore those who need it and thus increase inequalities when financial institutions are of low quality and credit provision is misguided. Also, thanks to the increase in foreign direct investment (FDI) in the host economy. Since capital and skilled labor tend to be complements, opening the capital account can increase the demand for skilled labor compared to unskilled labor, leading to higher wage inequality.

Financial development participate also to the increase of income inequality. Our result join some previous studies, for example, Dollar and Kraay 28, Beck and al. 29 show that in the early stage of financial development, financial sector may charge high set up cost against financial services during to gain advantages from the screening and risk pooling which is beyond the affordability of poor individuals. Hence, poor individuals are unable to come out from the circle of income inequality. Claessens and Perotti 30 provided another reason due to which poor people are unable to access the benefit of financial development. They argued that since poor individuals are not much educated, formal financial sector does not seem to prefer such un-educated or less-educated persons to offer loans, and hence in many high-income countries, financial sector has dualism in financial services. Greenwood and Jovanovich 31 proposed a non-linear relationship between financial development and income inequality or what we may call as ‘‘inverted-U’’ hypothesis. They argued that initially financial development increases income inequality and improves income distribution once financial sector matures.

Financial development combined with a periods of liberalization (KAOPENXDEV indicator) also participate to the rise of income inequality, but the impact became more much low 13. The impact of financial liberalization on inequality seems to be conditioned by the level of financial development. This later strengthens the inequality-raising impact of financial liberalization, i.e. financial liberalization increases inequality in particular in those countries in which the level of financial development is already high.

For the other composite index (KAOPENXCRISIS), and oppositely to the finding of Furceri and Loungani 11, the impact on income inequality is negative. It should be noted that not all the financial crises exacerbate inequalities due to compensating effects 32. On the one hand, they can reduce the inequalities, because bankruptcies and the fall in the prices of assets usually affect more the more affluent. On the other, the financial crises related to sustainable recessions can hit disproportionately the poorest - and dig the inequalities.

The financial globalization index and the trade variable reduces income inequality 33. In countries with strong financial institutions, financial globalization may reduce inequality by allowing better consumption smoothing and lower volatility and trade openness exerts an equalizing effect.

The successive addition of other explanatory variables of inequalities show that the indicator of crisis, the trade openness and the research & development tend to reduce inequality. Whereas, the school enrollment favors them.

The impacts of financial liberalization and financial development on income inequalities are source of ambiguities 11, 13, 17. The repartition on countries regarding their income categories help us to response to these conflicts.

Based on the results of Table 7, we can conclude that financial development for low-income countries (which is weak comparing to others categories of income countries){8} participate to the increase of inequalities and act in opposite direction to the capital account liberalization (The Wald test of causation in Table 8 confirms the results of Table 7). For the high-income countries (which have advanced stages on capital account liberalization), financial development act also in opposite direction by increasing the inequalities (reduced by capital account liberalization). For the middle-income countries (by hypothesis have a moderate financial development and account capital liberalization), both variables acts to reduce income inequalities. The opposite signs of the coefficients of KAOPEN and LF_Dev show clearly that capital account liberalization and financial development levels (between low and high-income countries) act in opposite directions in terms of rising of income inequality. For the globalization index same results are found with the baseline models, it tends to reduce income inequalities for all income categories of countries{9}.

The subdivision of the analysis period shows that the results of the first period are similar to the previous results (a negative impact of KAOPEN and LGLOBAL indexes and a positive impact of LF_Dev). The second period does not present significant coefficients and shows that the majority of the impact on income inequality is captured by the variation of the GINI index of the previous year (t-1) (value of 0.72 for the coefficient with a "t-student" very significant 15.28).

Variance decompositions show the percent of the total variation in one variable that is explained by the shock of another variable after a certain amount of time. They therefore provide an indication of the magnitude of the total effect one variable exerts on another. We report the total effect accumulated over 10 years. The variance decompositions for the different models are presented in Table 9. The results, for the baseline model, shows a low impact of KAOPEN, LF_Dev and LGLOBAL on the DLGINI index. These indexes affect the variation of inequality index with the respective variation of 4.7%; and 8.6% and 8.2%. This impact is particularly very low for two models: the high-income model and the second period model (has never exceed 5.8%).

The Impulse response function (Graph 3) describe the reaction of one variable to the innovations in another variable in the system, while holding all other shocks equal to zero. The first result of the IRF graph (the last right column of the graph){10} shows that the impact of financial liberalization on income inequality is not immediately. The shocks of the financial liberalization index (capital account, financial development and globalization) take on average 5 to 10 years. The second outcome is that the shocks{11} caused by our different indicators are very low and presents slight shocks. We can conclude that the indicators of financial liberalization cause small but persistent shocks on the variation of income inequality.

7. Conclusion

Taken in the entirety of the sample of 162 countries, the liberalization of the capital account as well as the financial development have a positive impact on income inequalities. In contrast, globalization tends to reduce these inequalities.

The interest of this study is much more apparent with the subdivision of the global sample according to the income categories of the countries. It seems that the degrees of liberalization of capital account and financial development play a key role in determining this impact. Great part of the various results of previous works may be due to this ignorance of this subdivision of income categories.

The countries, which are the reduction of inequalities, one of their major objectives will no doubt have to structure the liberalization in reconciling this priority and the benefits of an increase of productivity and growth. We also find that the impact of liberalization on the inequalities is mitigated when the country has a high level of financial development. This reinforces the idea that the benefits of liberalization outweigh its costs in the countries having exceeded a certain level of financial development.

The 1980-1990 decade seems to bring more information about this relationship, while the results from recent years are more ambiguous (non-significant results between 1991 and 2015).

Finally, the Gini coefficient change slowly in the Duration: The variations have a standard deviation of 2%. The variance decomposition and the impulse response functions analysis shows that impact of shocks of financial liberalization on income inequality are very small but persistent (it stays from 5 to 10 years). This impact are even confirms after the considering of several other factors of inequality, such as the opening of trade, the evolution of the school enrollment, and the technological progress.

Notes

1. This database presents several types of inequality; we have taken statistics on income inequality. It also shows the GINI indicator for 1 percentile of the total population for each country and ranges from 1 to 100 percentiles. We calculated the average of these 100 percentiles to have a single GINI indicator of the entire population.

2. Although that empirical verification of this relationship financial liberalization/globalization is not certain due to the diversity of indicators used for the two process.

3. CRISIS range from 0 to 7. Used by Reinhart, Camen M. and Kenneth S. Rogoff (2010) and based on 7 types of crises: currency crisis; Inflation Crisis; Stock market crash; Sovereign debt crises "domestic"; Sovereign debt crises "external"; Banking Crises. "1" is given for each type of these crises.

4. We have applied the logarithm to these variables.

5. Many others variables can be included in this analysis and have a clear impact on inequality. Among these variables, we note GDP, inflation, population, the economic and political institutional quality… Unfortunately; we cannot use all this number of variables in a pvar.

6. To lighten the appendices we did not include the stability tests of our models, which confirm that these estimates are stable for all models, tested (Eigenvalue stability condition).

7. Except LSchool variable, for need of the progress of the estimate.

8. Based on previous works on financial liberalization and financial development, I suppose that low-income countries have low level of capital account liberalization and financial development, middle-income countries have average level and high-income countries are advanced.

9. I removed all the indicators in relationship with the crises (Crisis, KAOPENXCRISIS and KAOPENXDEV). Similarly, I don't use the variable research & development whose data exists only from 1996 and who risk to strongly reduce our statistical data.

10. We decline the interpretation of other graphics that can inform us on the causality in the opposite direction, DLGINI toward financial liberalization indexes, or, which also reflect the multiple shocks between the various indicators of financial liberalization.

11. The magnitude of the shock corresponds to one-unit standard deviation of the indicator used.

References

[1]  Rodrik D. 1997, Has Globalization Gone Too Far? April 1997, California Management Review 39(3).
In article      
 
[2]  Broner and Ventura. 2010. Rethinking the Effects of Financial Liberalization. NBER Working Paper No. w16640.
In article      
 
[3]  Love and Zicchino. 2006. Financial development and dynamic investment behavior: Evidence from panel VAR. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 46 (2006) 190-210.
In article      View Article
 
[4]  Summers, Kravis and Heston. 1984. Changes in the world income distribution. Journal of Policy Modeling, 1984, vol. 6, issue 2, 237-269.
In article      
 
[5]  De Haan, J., and J.-E. Sturm. 2017. Finance and Income Inequality: A Review and New Evidence. European Journal of Political Economy.
In article      View Article
 
[6]  Banerjee and Newman. 1993. Occupational Choice and the Process of Development. Journal of Political Economy, 1993, vol. 101, issue 2, 274-98.
In article      
 
[7]  Abiad, A., Oomes N., and Ueda K.: The Quality Effect: Does Financial Liberalization Improve the Allocation of Capital? Journal of Development Economics 87: 270-282. (2008).
In article      View Article
 
[8]  Delis, M. D., I. Hasan, and P. Kazakis. 2014. “Bank Regulations and Income Inequality: Empirical Evidence.” Review of Finance 18 (5): 1811-1846.
In article      View Article
 
[9]  Li, J., and H. Yu. 2014. “Income Inequality and Financial Reform in Asia: The Role of Human Capital.” Applied Economics 46: 2920-2935.
In article      View Article
 
[10]  Jaumotte and Buitron. 2015. Inequality and Labor Market Institutions. IMF Staff Discussion Note 15/14.
In article      
 
[11]  Furceri, D. and Loungani P., 2015. Capital Account Liberalization and Inequality. IMF Working Paper 15/243.
In article      
 
[12]  LaGarda, Guillermo & Gallagher, Kevin & Linares, Jennifer, 2016. "Capital Openness and Income Inequality: A Cross-Country Study and The Role of CCT in Latin America," MPRA Paper 74181, University Library of Munich, Germany.
In article      View Article
 
[13]  De Haana, Pleningera and Sturm. 2018. Does the impact of financial liberalization on income inequality depend on financial development? Some new evidence. Applied Economics Letters, 2018 Vol. 25, No. 5, 313-316.
In article      View Article
 
[14]  Abiad, A., Detragiache E., and Tressel T.: A New Database of Financial Reforms. IMF Staff Papers 57: 281-302. (2010).
In article      View Article
 
[15]  Chinn, M. D., and H. Ito. 2006. “What Matters for Financial Development? Capital Controls, Institutions, andInteractions.” Journal of Development Economics 81: 163-192.
In article      View Article
 
[16]  Chinn, M. D., and H. Ito. 2008. “A New Measure of Financial Openness.” Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis: Research and Practice 10: 309-322.
In article      View Article
 
[17]  Bumann, S., and R. Lensink. 2016. “Capital Account Liberalization and Income Inequality.” Journal of International Money and Finance 61: 143-162.
In article      View Article
 
[18]  Jaumotte, F., Lall, S., Papageorgiou, C., 2013. Rising income inequality: technology, or trade and financial globalization? IMF Economic Review 61, 271-309.
In article      View Article
 
[19]  Dabla-Norris, E., Kochhar, K., Ricka, F., Suphaphiphat, N., Tsounta, E., 2015. Causes and consequences of income inequality: a global perspective. IMF Staff Discussion Note 15/13, IMF, Washington DC.
In article      
 
[20]  Solt, F. 2009. “Standardizing the World Income Inequality Database.” Social Science Quarterly 90: 231-242.
In article      View Article
 
[21]  McKinnon R. I. 1973. Money and Capital in Economic Development. The American Political Science Review, Vol. 68, No. 4 (Dec. 1974), pp. 1822-1824.
In article      
 
[22]  Shaw, Edward S. 1973. Financial Deepening in Economic Development, New York, Oxford University Press.
In article      
 
[23]  Demirgüç-Kunt and Detragiache. 1998. Financial Liberalization and Financial Fragility. IMF Working Paper No. 98/83.
In article      
 
[24]  Čihák, M., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., Feyen, E., Levine, R., 2012. Benchmarking financial systems around the world. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 6175, World Bank, Washington DC.
In article      
 
[25]  Prasad, Kose, Rogoff, and Wei. 2009. Financial Globalization: A Reappraisal. IMF Staff Papers (2009) 56, 8-62..
In article      View Article
 
[26]  Broner, and Ventura. : Enforcement problems and secondary markets. Journal of the European Economic Association 6, 683-94. (2008).
In article      View Article
 
[27]  Stiglitz, J. 2000. Capital Market Liberalization, Economic Growth, and Instability. World Development Vol. 28, No. 6, pp. 1075±1086.
In article      
 
[28]  Dollar, D. and Kraay, A. 2002. Growth is good for the poor, Journal of Economic Growth, vol. 7, pp. 195-225.
In article      View Article
 
[29]  Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt A., and Levine R.: Law, Endowments and Finance. Journal of Financial Economics 70, 137-81. (2003).
In article      View Article
 
[30]  Claessens, S., Perotti, E., 2007. Finance and inequality: channels and evidence. Journal of Comparative Economics 35, 748-773.
In article      View Article
 
[31]  Greenwood, J., Jovanovic, B., 1990. Financial development, growth, and the distribution of income. Journal of Political Economy 98, 1076-1107.
In article      View Article
 
[32]  Otker-Robe and Podpiera. 2013. The social impact of financial crises: evidence from the global financial crisis. World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper. WPS6703.
In article      View Article
 
[33]  Shang-Jin Wei and Yi Wu. 2018. Globalization and Inequality: Evidence from Within China NBER Working Paper No. 8611.
In article      
 
[34]  Agnello, L., Mallick S. K., and Sousa R. M.: Financial Reforms and Income Inequality. Economics Letters 116: 583-587. (2012).
In article      View Article
 
[35]  Brambor, T., Clark W., and Golder M.: Understanding Interaction Models: Improving Empirical Analyses.” Political Analysis 14: 63-82. (2006).
In article      View Article
 
[36]  Naceur, S. B., and R. Zhang. 2016. Financial Development, Inequality and Poverty: Some International Evidence. IMF Working Paper 16/32.
In article      
 

Published with license by Science and Education Publishing, Copyright © 2019 Chokri Zehri and Hamadi Ben Abid

Creative CommonsThis work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License. To view a copy of this license, visit https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/

Cite this article:

Normal Style
Chokri Zehri, Hamadi Ben Abid. Impact of Financial Liberalization on Income Inequality: A PVAR Approach. International Journal of Econometrics and Financial Management. Vol. 7, No. 1, 2019, pp 1-11. https://pubs.sciepub.com/ijefm/7/1/1
MLA Style
Zehri, Chokri, and Hamadi Ben Abid. "Impact of Financial Liberalization on Income Inequality: A PVAR Approach." International Journal of Econometrics and Financial Management 7.1 (2019): 1-11.
APA Style
Zehri, C. , & Abid, H. B. (2019). Impact of Financial Liberalization on Income Inequality: A PVAR Approach. International Journal of Econometrics and Financial Management, 7(1), 1-11.
Chicago Style
Zehri, Chokri, and Hamadi Ben Abid. "Impact of Financial Liberalization on Income Inequality: A PVAR Approach." International Journal of Econometrics and Financial Management 7, no. 1 (2019): 1-11.
Share
  • Table 6. One-step Generalized Method of Moments Dynamic Estimation Results – Sample all panel - Basic model
[1]  Rodrik D. 1997, Has Globalization Gone Too Far? April 1997, California Management Review 39(3).
In article      
 
[2]  Broner and Ventura. 2010. Rethinking the Effects of Financial Liberalization. NBER Working Paper No. w16640.
In article      
 
[3]  Love and Zicchino. 2006. Financial development and dynamic investment behavior: Evidence from panel VAR. The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 46 (2006) 190-210.
In article      View Article
 
[4]  Summers, Kravis and Heston. 1984. Changes in the world income distribution. Journal of Policy Modeling, 1984, vol. 6, issue 2, 237-269.
In article      
 
[5]  De Haan, J., and J.-E. Sturm. 2017. Finance and Income Inequality: A Review and New Evidence. European Journal of Political Economy.
In article      View Article
 
[6]  Banerjee and Newman. 1993. Occupational Choice and the Process of Development. Journal of Political Economy, 1993, vol. 101, issue 2, 274-98.
In article      
 
[7]  Abiad, A., Oomes N., and Ueda K.: The Quality Effect: Does Financial Liberalization Improve the Allocation of Capital? Journal of Development Economics 87: 270-282. (2008).
In article      View Article
 
[8]  Delis, M. D., I. Hasan, and P. Kazakis. 2014. “Bank Regulations and Income Inequality: Empirical Evidence.” Review of Finance 18 (5): 1811-1846.
In article      View Article
 
[9]  Li, J., and H. Yu. 2014. “Income Inequality and Financial Reform in Asia: The Role of Human Capital.” Applied Economics 46: 2920-2935.
In article      View Article
 
[10]  Jaumotte and Buitron. 2015. Inequality and Labor Market Institutions. IMF Staff Discussion Note 15/14.
In article      
 
[11]  Furceri, D. and Loungani P., 2015. Capital Account Liberalization and Inequality. IMF Working Paper 15/243.
In article      
 
[12]  LaGarda, Guillermo & Gallagher, Kevin & Linares, Jennifer, 2016. "Capital Openness and Income Inequality: A Cross-Country Study and The Role of CCT in Latin America," MPRA Paper 74181, University Library of Munich, Germany.
In article      View Article
 
[13]  De Haana, Pleningera and Sturm. 2018. Does the impact of financial liberalization on income inequality depend on financial development? Some new evidence. Applied Economics Letters, 2018 Vol. 25, No. 5, 313-316.
In article      View Article
 
[14]  Abiad, A., Detragiache E., and Tressel T.: A New Database of Financial Reforms. IMF Staff Papers 57: 281-302. (2010).
In article      View Article
 
[15]  Chinn, M. D., and H. Ito. 2006. “What Matters for Financial Development? Capital Controls, Institutions, andInteractions.” Journal of Development Economics 81: 163-192.
In article      View Article
 
[16]  Chinn, M. D., and H. Ito. 2008. “A New Measure of Financial Openness.” Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis: Research and Practice 10: 309-322.
In article      View Article
 
[17]  Bumann, S., and R. Lensink. 2016. “Capital Account Liberalization and Income Inequality.” Journal of International Money and Finance 61: 143-162.
In article      View Article
 
[18]  Jaumotte, F., Lall, S., Papageorgiou, C., 2013. Rising income inequality: technology, or trade and financial globalization? IMF Economic Review 61, 271-309.
In article      View Article
 
[19]  Dabla-Norris, E., Kochhar, K., Ricka, F., Suphaphiphat, N., Tsounta, E., 2015. Causes and consequences of income inequality: a global perspective. IMF Staff Discussion Note 15/13, IMF, Washington DC.
In article      
 
[20]  Solt, F. 2009. “Standardizing the World Income Inequality Database.” Social Science Quarterly 90: 231-242.
In article      View Article
 
[21]  McKinnon R. I. 1973. Money and Capital in Economic Development. The American Political Science Review, Vol. 68, No. 4 (Dec. 1974), pp. 1822-1824.
In article      
 
[22]  Shaw, Edward S. 1973. Financial Deepening in Economic Development, New York, Oxford University Press.
In article      
 
[23]  Demirgüç-Kunt and Detragiache. 1998. Financial Liberalization and Financial Fragility. IMF Working Paper No. 98/83.
In article      
 
[24]  Čihák, M., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., Feyen, E., Levine, R., 2012. Benchmarking financial systems around the world. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 6175, World Bank, Washington DC.
In article      
 
[25]  Prasad, Kose, Rogoff, and Wei. 2009. Financial Globalization: A Reappraisal. IMF Staff Papers (2009) 56, 8-62..
In article      View Article
 
[26]  Broner, and Ventura. : Enforcement problems and secondary markets. Journal of the European Economic Association 6, 683-94. (2008).
In article      View Article
 
[27]  Stiglitz, J. 2000. Capital Market Liberalization, Economic Growth, and Instability. World Development Vol. 28, No. 6, pp. 1075±1086.
In article      
 
[28]  Dollar, D. and Kraay, A. 2002. Growth is good for the poor, Journal of Economic Growth, vol. 7, pp. 195-225.
In article      View Article
 
[29]  Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt A., and Levine R.: Law, Endowments and Finance. Journal of Financial Economics 70, 137-81. (2003).
In article      View Article
 
[30]  Claessens, S., Perotti, E., 2007. Finance and inequality: channels and evidence. Journal of Comparative Economics 35, 748-773.
In article      View Article
 
[31]  Greenwood, J., Jovanovic, B., 1990. Financial development, growth, and the distribution of income. Journal of Political Economy 98, 1076-1107.
In article      View Article
 
[32]  Otker-Robe and Podpiera. 2013. The social impact of financial crises: evidence from the global financial crisis. World Bank, Policy Research Working Paper. WPS6703.
In article      View Article
 
[33]  Shang-Jin Wei and Yi Wu. 2018. Globalization and Inequality: Evidence from Within China NBER Working Paper No. 8611.
In article      
 
[34]  Agnello, L., Mallick S. K., and Sousa R. M.: Financial Reforms and Income Inequality. Economics Letters 116: 583-587. (2012).
In article      View Article
 
[35]  Brambor, T., Clark W., and Golder M.: Understanding Interaction Models: Improving Empirical Analyses.” Political Analysis 14: 63-82. (2006).
In article      View Article
 
[36]  Naceur, S. B., and R. Zhang. 2016. Financial Development, Inequality and Poverty: Some International Evidence. IMF Working Paper 16/32.
In article