In many developing countries, conditional cash transfer (CCT) programs have a significant social impact. They seek to combat poverty through redistributive transfers, and to combat transmission of poverty through generations by investing in human capital in the form of children. Several studies show that these programs have succeeded in increasing the demand for education and reducing child labor. This paper aims to assess the impact of Morocco’s conditional cash transfer program (Tayssir) on school attendance and labor of rural children aged 6 to 15 years. Using data from the Household Panel Survey conducted by the National Observatory for Human Development (ONDH), we estimate first an Average-treatment-Effect (ATE) by using Propensity Score Matching. This initial analysis shows that Tayssir has significantly increased enrollment rates and reduced child labor. In order to refine the analysis and due to non-compliance with the criteria of eligibility, we also estimate a Local Average Treatment Effect (LATE) by using the eligibility rule as an instrumental variable. This second analysis shows that Tayssir has had no significant effect on children whose participation was assigned under the eligibility rule (the compliers). This suggests that the program requires additional measures.
As one of the most important factors in human development (Schultz 1; Becker 2), education must be developed to help the poor escape poverty. School dropout rates reflect the level of poverty, and experience shows, especially in developing countries, that children from materially deprived households are the least educated. This indicates the crucial role that public education can play in combating poverty. Starting in the 1990s, many developing countries, especially in Latin America and South Asia, have invested heavily in education. Since 1994, Bangladesh’s Food For Education (FFE) program has provided ‘in-kind’ transfers to low-income households with children attending school. By the same logic, since 1997 the Mexican program Progresa has conditioned cash transfers on school attendance in low-income rural localities. These programs have several objectives. First, they aim to combat current poverty through redistributive transfers. Second, they seek to reduce future poverty. Conditional cash transfer programs are based on two assumptions. The first is that limited resources prevent parents from sending their children to school. The second is that educational level is a significant determinant of future poverty.
In the case of Morocco, the approach has been one of lump sum transfers. Studies by the High Commission for Planning (HCP) show it to have failed. According to the 2001 National Survey of Household Consumption and Expenditure, the wealthiest quintile of households receives over 40% of food subsidies and over 50% of subsidies for secondary and higher education. Thus, the lump sum transfer approach has helped to increase economic inequality, making it essential to seek an alternative policy in support of disadvantaged citizens.
Tayssir is one of a new set of policies aimed directly at improving the target population’s standard of living. It helps needy households finance their children’s school costs. The program combats school dropouts in rural Morocco by neutralizing factors that affect the demand for education negatively, particularly in disadvantaged areas. This paper aims at analysing the impact of cash transfer on access to education and on child labor. We start from the hypothesis that cash transfers to poor households, conditional on their children attending school, can stimulate demand for education and reduction of child labor (Ravallion and Wodon 3; De Janvry and al 4; Skoufias and al 5; Kilburn and al 6; Attanasio and al 7; Del Carpio and al 8).
Unlike previous studies (Benhassine & al 9 and Gazeaud & Ricard 10), our study also aims to analyze the effect of Tayssir on the probability of child labor as an indirect effect of cash transfers. Theoretically, they are expected to reduce the child labor through two mechanisms (Edmonds and Schady 11). First, beneficiary children have to attend school regularly. This reduce the time for child work and increases, however, the time they spend in school. Second, increasing family income through a cash transfers can decrease the occurrence of working children, considering the fact the extra revenue may releases children from their economic tasks (Hidayatina and Garces-Ozanne 12).
In order to assess the effect of Morocco’s conditional cash transfers program on school attendance and child labor we estimate first an Average-treatment-Effect (ATE) by using Propensity Score Matching. The findings is in line with Benhassine & al 9 and Gazeaud & Ricard 10. In order to refine the analysis and due to non-compliance with the criteria of eligibility, we also estimate a Local Average Treatment Effect (LATE) by using the eligibility rule as an instrumental variable (Hidayatina and Garces-Ozanne 12). This second analysis, however, shows that Tayssir has had no significant effect on children whose participation was assigned under the eligibility rule (the neediest).
The remainder of the paper is structured as follows: Section 2 reviews the literature. The third section outlines the data used in the Moroccan context. Section 4 presents our initial analysis; Section 5 gives a refined analysis using instrumental variables. The final section concludes.
Here we discuss the theoretical justification of policies to combat school dropouts. Implementing such policies requires an analysis of the determinants of dropouts. Understanding the determinants allows decision-maker to identify the populations concerned, and thus target measures in their direction. The literature shows that school dropout stems not only from characteristics of individual children (De Vreyer 13; Buchmann 14; Jimerson and al 15; Glewwe 16), but also from a set of family, socio-economic and community factors (Vinas-Forcade and al 17; Itzhaki and al 18; Glewwe and Kassouf 19).
No et al 20 conclude that poorly educated or illiterate parents normally do not regard schooling essential for a child’s cultural and social development. Well-educated parents consider it essential, meaning that their children feel more comfortable at school and are supported in their studies. The authors also find enrollment to be hampered by the cost of school fees, transport and school supplies.
In addition to direct costs, some households also bear indirect (opportunity) costs. This can happen when children go to school instead of participating in household economic activity. In other words, school enrollment also depends on the household’s ability to forego such participation. This condition is difficult to apply to poor families, where children support family income (Jacoby and Skoufias 21; Naseer and al 22). Conditional cash transfer programs require removal of this constraint on demand for education.
As regards site of residence, Diagne 23 concludes that school dropout is higher in rural than urban areas. This is due to several factors: school infrastructure is more developed in cities than rural areas, rural children live further from their schools, and rural parents are less inclined to view their children as human capital.
Other writers find school dropout resulting from a combination of frustrations, produced by lower academic achievement and problems of relations with peers, teachers and parents. Clearly efforts to combat dropout should be made while the child attends school, because it is easier to keep him in school than to get him to go back (Rumberger 24; Gao and al 25).
2.2. Impacts of Conditional Cash TransfersIn this section, we review studies analyzing the impact of conditional cash transfers in environments similar to Morocco’s. Using longitudinal data from the 1998-2005 school census (8 years), Glewwe et Kassouf 19 analyze the impact of Brazil’s cash transfer program ‘Bolsa Escola’ (renamed Bolsa Familia) on the demand for education. Comparing enrollment rates in public schools benefiting from the program with non-benefiting schools, in its first two years Bolsa Escola increased the enrollment rate in the first four grades of primary school by 2.8%.
Attanasio et al 26 seek to measure the effect of Colombia’s cash transfer program (Familias en Acción) on school attendance and child labor. Using the propensity score matching estimator, the study shows that conditional cash transfers increased the schooling rate of children aged 14 to 17 by 5 to 7 percentage points.
Still in Latin America, where there are several conditional cash transfer programs, Skoufias and al 5 used experimental data and double difference estimators to assess the impact of Mexico’s cash transfer program “Progresa” on school attendance. Their estimates show significant increases in school attendance of both boys and girls, accompanied by significant reduction in their participation in labor.
Several studies had limited it's researches to the impact of cash transfer programs on child labor. They conclude that cash transfers appear to be effective strategies for reducing child work in developing countries.
Hidayatina and Garces-Ozanne 12 show that the Indonesian intervention (Program Keluarga Harapan) reduces the probability of child work in household tasks and economic activities. In Nicaragua, Gee 27 find that the cash transfers program (Red de Proteccion Social) reduced both the probability of occurrence (engaging in work) and the duration (weekly hours) of child labor. The impact of cash transfers programs on child labor depends not only on the definition of the working outcomes of children, but also on the frequency of receiving subsidies. In Philippines, De Hoop and al 28 conclude that the cash transfers generate an increase in children’s working for pay, because the program only provided a partial subsidy. This implies that children have to work in order to cover their school fees.
The data used here come from the Household Panel Survey conducted by the National Observatory for Human Development{1} (ONDH). It is a sample of 8,000 households followed during three waves in 2012, 2013 and 2015. In this study we use the wave of 2015.{2} The sample of 8,000 households was chosen to represent all categories of Moroccan households. Geographically, the survey covered all the country’s regions. In addition to geographical representativeness, it also covers the main dimensions of human development, namely education, health, employment and household consumption expenditure. ONDH main objective is to evaluate impact of human development policies and propose further interventions to enhance human development in Morocco.
3.2. Moroccan Education SystemAs in most countries, Morocco’s education system comprises the three main levels of primary, secondary and higher. Schooling in Morocco is compulsory from the age of six (Gouzi and El Aoufi 29). The system consists of six years of primary school, three years of intermediate, three years of upper secondary, and tertiary education. The primary education cycle serves children aged 6 to 11 years, comprising six years of study towards the certificate of primary studies. Intermediate school serves children aged 12 to 14 years having earned the primary certificate.
Upper secondary school, comprising three years, is open to students having completed intermediate school. The first year offers a core curriculum, while the following two years form the baccalaureate cycle. Primary education and the secondary school cycle are compulsory for children aged 6 to 15 years.
3.3. Morocco’s Conditional Cash Transfer ProgramManaged by the Moroccan Association for School Support (AMAS) in partnership with the Ministry of Education, Tayssir, implemented since 2008, is a conditional cash transfer program for poor households. It is designed to help neutralize the economic constraints affecting education demand in rural areas. Tayssir is conditional on effective schooling of target children (fewer than four absences per month). It targets schools located in municipalities where the poverty rate is above 30% according to the High Planning Commission (HCP)’s 2004 poverty map. To benefit from the program, a child must be aged 6 to 15 years and enrolled in a designated school. Tayssir’s pilot phase was implemented during 2008-10 in five regions. It was then extended to all schools in eligible municipalities. The monthly transfer amounts to 60DH (≈$5.85) per child for the first two years of primary, 80DH (≈$7.79) for the following two years, 100DH (≈$9.74) for the last two years of primary, and finally 140DH (≈$13.64) for high school students. Tayssir transfers are much lower than other similar programs (Table 1).
This section presents the initial methodology used to assess Tayssir’s impact. The sample comprised 3,029 children, aged 6 to 15, evenly distributed among boys and girls, from 1,680{3} rural households. Table 2 presents data on those households, showing a Tayssir participation rate of 24.45%.
4.1. Propensity Score MatchingThe main object of evaluating a program’s impact is to derive its results and show to what extent it has led to changes--i.e. an impact evaluation is structured around the following question: what is a program’s causal impact (direct and exclusive) on a given outcome? The challenge lies in identifying what benefits the program’s beneficiaries would have enjoyed had they not participated in the program (the counterfactual scenario). For this reason, creating a comparison group tells us what would have happened had a participant not taken part. We use the propensity score matching method (PMS) suggested by Rosenbaum and Rubin 31 to create a comparison group. This method consists of matching actual participants (treatment group) to a group of non-participants (control group) with similar observable characteristics. We estimate the probability of participation in the program by members of the two groups. This probability is termed the propensity score. Estimating this score requires a probit regression model. The exogenous variables used are the child’s age and sex, annual household consumption expenditure per capita, the distance between home and the nearest primary school, and a composite indicator of the standard of living{4} (see Appendix A).
Once the probability of participation is estimated for all members of the sample, we use the Nearest Neighbor Matching algorithm suggested by Rubin 32 to match beneficiaries to the closest non-beneficiaries.
Next, we use graphical analysis to verify the comparability of the two groups, based on comparing their propensity scores before and after matching (Figure 1 and Figure 2 above). We apply the standardized difference test (Rosenbaum and Rubin 33) to test the validity of balancing the two groups’ characteristics. This test measures the degree of bias reduction by comparing, for each variable used in the propensity score, the means of participants and nonparticipants before and after matching (see Appendix C).
4.2. Results and DiscussionThe propensity score matching method shows Tayssir significantly increasing school enrollment and reducing child labor (Table 3). All differences yield significant Student T values.
Enrollment rate is calculated by dividing the number of children enrolled by the size of the sample (3,029 children). Child labor rate was calculated using the same formula.
We note also that participation in Tayssir increases enrolment of rural children by 7.55 percentage points. This result is in line with international experience showing that cash transfers are important in helping poor households keep their children in school (Bauchet and al 34; Giang and Nguyen 35). We also find that Tayssir reduces the child labor rate by 7.38 percentage points. This is in line with our expectation, insofar as transfers to poor households reduce the opportunity cost of education (Hidayatina and Garces-Ozanne 12; Del Carpio et al 8).
However, to make the assessment relevant, we need to check the relevance of the eligibility rule. In other words, if households are chosen solely based on the eligibility variable (the municipal poverty rate), this means that every household i from an eligible municipality j is a beneficiary of the program (Ti =1 if Pj > 30%). In this case, participation in the program is determined, and depends only on eligibility. However, as shown in Table 4 below, participation in Tayssir is not determined, and presents ambiguity. About 71.42% of households (1200/1680) participate because they are eligible. However, about 25.23% (424/1680) are eligible but do not participate, and 3.3% (56/1680) are not eligible but do participate.
Statistically, it implies that: P(T=1|Z=1)≠1 and P(T=1|Z=0)≠0 (see Givord 36). To solve this, we follow Chong & Yáñez-Pagans 37 and Choi & Lee 38. We estimate a Local Average Treatment Effect (LATE) by using the eligibility rule as an instrumental variable. As non-compliance in this case is two-sided (Table 4 below), the LATE allow us to estimate the effect on actual beneficiaries (see more details in the next section).
On the other hand, this analysis demonstrates the endogenous nature of participation in Tayssir. Accordingly, the instrumental variable {5} (IV) method is the most appropriate approach to analyzing Tayssir’s causal effect. To begin with, it captures the exogenous variation of participation. This variation can then be used to identify the causal effect (Givord 36).
With the instrumental variable method, an instrument "Z" and a vector of exogenous variables "X" explain participation in Tayssir. Representing the eligibility rule, instrument "Z takes 1 if the child is eligible, zero otherwise. We consider the following specification:
![]() | (1) |
where "T" designates the treatment variable, taking 1 if the child is a beneficiary of Tayssir and zero otherwise. "X" is a vector of child and household characteristics, and "w" is an unobserved error term. As the instrument represents the eligibility rule, it is most likely to be correlated with participation. We assume that the unobserved errors are not correlated with the instrument. We set: cov (u, Z) = 0. If this is correct, Tayssir’s causal effect is obtained by estimating the second specification:
![]() | (2) |
where is obtained by estimating equation (1). The second equation gives us Tayssir’s causal effect for children whose participation is assigned by the eligibility rule (compliers). This is called the Local Average Treatment Effect (LATE). For cases with a binary treatment and instrument, Table 5 defines four subpopulations. LATE gives the average treatment effect on compliers only (Angrist et al 39).
Estimation of equation (2) shows that the eligibility rule has a positive and significant impact on participation (Table 6 below). The partial R2 and the Fisher statistic (Hahn and Hausman 40) are statistically significant (see Appendix D). These results confirm that the eligibility rule is a relevant instrument for participation in Tayssir. Although the instrument and the treatment variable are correlated (cov (T, Z) ≠ 0), we must ensure that the instrument (the eligibility rule) is not correlated with the equation 2 error term (the exclusion restriction). Since eligibility for Tayssir is not effectively subject to the level of household resources (targeting by municipalities), we assume that the eligibility rule cannot directly affect the outcome.
5.3. Results and DiscussionWe note that: 1) school attendance variable is equal to 1 if child enrolled, 0 otherwise; 2) Child labor variable is also unity if child work, 0 otherwise. Unfortunately, the survey do not provide information about the type of child work (household chores, paid work…).
Our estimates show that Tayssir neither affects school attendance nor reduces child labor significantly (Table 6 below). Accordingly, we suggest policymakers should question its effectiveness.
In other words, a program such as Tayssir enhances demand for education given favorable conditions of schooling. When the school is far from home, children have to walk long distances. This generates transport costs and requires physical effort, particularly given a harsh climate. To take these conditions into account, we perform another analysis on two subsamples, comprising children who walk less or more than three kilometers. In the second subsample, the effect of the cross variable (Eligibility × Participation) on school attendance is not significant (see Appendices E and F). This means that Tayssir’s small transfers, once they cover clothing and school supplies, do not suffice to finance transport costs. In such a situation, the cash-transfer program is insufficient to improve school attendance, especially in disadvantaged areas.
Some eligible rural municipalities are mountainous areas with poor roads. Their children must cross rivers to reach school; occasional flooding hampers school attendance. In those areas cash transfer does not suffice to encourage parents to enroll their children. Tayssir’s insignificant impact may also be explained by the remoteness and inaccessibility of other basic social services. In our sample, eligible households are supposed to walk more than five kilometers to reach the nearest health center. When a nearer health center helps the beneficiary household save on a sick child’s transport costs, Tayssir transfers can be restricted to educational needs.
Moreover, 51.44% of eligible households lack running water, and depend on children to fetch their water. This cuts into time for school and homework, raising the risk of dropout. Poor communities use their children to support family income, thus minimizing Tayssir’s reduction of child labor. Tayssir’s modest impact may also be due to irrelevant targeting. Transfers are supposed to be targeted to the neediest, but municipalities commit errors of inclusion and exclusion.
Conditional cash transfer programs play an important social role. They seek to combat poverty and promote accumulation of human capital in the form of the beneficiary children. Several studies have shown the positive effect of these programs on demand for education. This paper’s contribution is to evaluate the impact of Morocco’s cash transfer program on school attendance and child labor. Initial results show that Tayssir has increased school attendance and reduced child labor. However, estimation by instrumental variables shows that the program has no significant effect on households whose participation coincides with the eligibility rule (compliers). Several factors may explain this, notably lack of basic infrastructure and irrelevance of the targeting method. From a methodological viewpoint, it is not certain that the insignificant impact can be generalized to the entire population. In other words, the instrumental variable estimator measures Tayssir’s impact only on compliers. Moreover, school dropout is not only due to lack of resources. In some cases the decision to quit school results from mounting frustration caused by academic failure as well as difficult relationships with peers, teachers and parents. Prevention strategies must be deployed while the child is in school, since it is much easier to keep him there than to make him go back. We evoke the case of the Indian program Multilingual Education Intervention, conducted in disadvantaged localities. Its aim is to increase the success rate of girls who master only their mother tongue. Once at school these girls are marginalized due to failure to master the language of instruction. Here the authorities have introduced a measure aimed directly at the cause of school dropout.
1. It is an organization whose mission is to assess the effect of human development policies implemented in Morocco.
2. We do not have access to the other waves of the survey.
3. This is the number of rural households with children aged 6 to 15 years.
4. It is calculated using the multiple correspondence analysis (MCA) technique. The variables used for this are presented in Appendix B.
5. Method IV controls the selection bias created by unobserved characteristics.
[1] | T.W. Schultz, Investment in human capital, Am. Econ. Rev. 51 (1961) 1-17. | ||
In article | |||
[2] | G.S. Becker, Human capital: A theoretical and empirical analysis, with special reference to education, University of Chicago press, 2009. | ||
In article | |||
[3] | M. Ravallion, Q. Wodon, Does Child Labor Displace Schooling? Evidence on Behavioral Responses to an Enrollment Subsidy. Policy Research Working Papers No. 2116., (1999). | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[4] | A. de Janvry, F. Finan, E. Sadoulet, How Effective are Educational Subsidies Programs for the Rural Poor? Progresa in Mexico, ARE Univ. Calif. Berkeley. (2001). | ||
In article | |||
[5] | E. Skoufias, S.W. Parker, J.R. Behrman, C. Pessino, Conditional cash transfers and their impact on child work and schooling: Evidence from the progresa program in mexico [with comments], Economia. 2 (2001) 45-96. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[6] | K. Kilburn, S. Handa, G. Angeles, P. Mvula, M. Tsoka, Short-term impacts of an unconditional cash transfer program on child schooling: Experimental evidence from Malawi, Econ. Educ. Rev. 59 (2017) 63-80. | ||
In article | View Article PubMed | ||
[7] | O. Attanasio, E. Fitzsimons, A. Gomez, The impact of a conditional education subsidy on school enrolment in Colombia, (2005). | ||
In article | |||
[8] | X. V Del Carpio, N. V Loayza, T. Wada, The impact of conditional cash transfers on the amount and type of child labor, World Dev. 80 (2016) 33-47. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[9] | N. Benhassine, F. Devoto, E. Duflo, P. Dupas, V. Pouliquen, Turning a shove into a nudge? A “labeled cash transfer” for education, Am. Econ. J. Econ. Policy. 7 (2015) 86-125. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[10] | J. Gazeaud, C. Ricard, Cash Transfers and School Performances: New Evidence from Morocco, 2020. | ||
In article | |||
[11] | E. V Edmonds, N. Schady, Poverty alleviation and child labor, Am. Econ. J. Econ. Policy. 4 (2012) 100-124. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[12] | A. Hidayatina, A. Garces-Ozanne, Can cash transfers mitigate child labour? Evidence from Indonesia’s cash transfer programme for poor students in Java, World Dev. Perspect. 15 (2019) 1. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[13] | P. De Vreyer, Une analyse économétrique de la demande d’éducation en Côte-d’Ivoire, Rev. Econ. Dev. 1 (1993) 49-79. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[14] | C. Buchmann, Family structure, parental perceptions, and child labor in Kenya: What factors determine who is enrolled in school?, Soc. Forces. 78 (2000) 1349-1378. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[15] | S. Jimerson, B. Egeland, L.A. Sroufe, B. Carlson, A prospective longitudinal study of high school dropouts examining multiple predictors across development, J. Sch. Psychol. 38 (2000) 525-549. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[16] | P. Glewwe, Schools and skills in developing countries: education policies and socioeconomic outcomes, J. Econ. Lit. 40 (2002) 436-482. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[17] | J. Vinas-Forcade, C. Mels, M. Valcke, I. Derluyn, Beyond academics: Dropout prevention summer school programs in the transition to secondary education, Int. J. Educ. Dev. 70 (2019) 102087. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[18] | Y. Itzhaki, H. Itzhaky, Y.B. Yablon, The contribution of parental and societal conditional regard to adjustment of high school dropouts, J. Adolesc. 62 (2018) 151-161. | ||
In article | View Article PubMed | ||
[19] | P. Glewwe, A.L. Kassouf, The impact of the Bolsa Escola/Familia conditional cash transfer program on enrollment, dropout rates and grade promotion in Brazil, J. Dev. Econ. 97 (2012) 505-517. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[20] | F. No, K. Taniguchi, Y. Hirakawa, School dropout at the basic education level in rural Cambodia: Identifying its causes through longitudinal survival analysis, Int. J. Educ. Dev. 49 (2016) 215-224. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[21] | H.G. Jacoby, E. Skoufias, Risk, financial markets, and human capital in a developing country, Rev. Econ. Stud. 64 (1997) 311-335. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[22] | M.N.U. Din, H. Dad, J. Iqbal, S.S.A. Shah, M.I. Niazi, Causes of male dropout rate in Pakistan, J. Coll. Teach. Learn. 8 (2011) 37-42. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[23] | A. Diagne, Pourquoi les enfants africains quittent-ils l’école? Un modèle hiérarchique multinomial des abandons dans l’éducation primaire au Sénégal, Actual. Econ. 86 (2010) 319-354. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[24] | R.W. Rumberger, Dropping out, Harvard University Press, 2011. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[25] | S. Gao, M. Yang, X. Wang, W. Min, S. Rozelle, Peer relations and dropout behavior: Evidence from junior high school students in northwest rural China, Int. J. Educ. Dev. 65 (2019) 134-143. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[26] | O. Attanasio, E. Fitzsimons, A. Gomez, M.I. Gutierrez, C. Meghir, A. Mesnard, Children’s schooling and work in the presence of a conditional cash transfer program in rural Colombia, Econ. Dev. Cult. Change. 58 (2010) 181-210. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[27] | K.A. Gee, Reducing child labour through conditional cash transfers: Evidence from nicaragua’s red de protección social, Dev. Policy Rev. 28 (2010) 711-732. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[28] | J. De Hoop, J. Friedman, E. Kandpal, F. Rosati, Child schooling and child work in the presence of a partial education subsidy, The World Bank, 2017. | ||
In article | View Article PubMed | ||
[29] | A.B. Gouzi, N. El Aoufi, La non-scolarisation au Maroc Une analyse en termes de coût d’opportunité, Crit. Économique. (2007). | ||
In article | |||
[30] | A. V Banerjee, R. Hanna, G.E. Kreindler, B.A. Olken, Debunking the stereotype of the lazy welfare recipient: Evidence from cash transfer programs, World Bank Res. Obs. 32 (2017) 155-184. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[31] | P.R. Rosenbaum, D.B. Rubin, The central role of the propensity score in observational studies for causal effects, Biometrika. 70 (1983) 41-55. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[32] | D.B. Rubin, The use of matched sampling and regression adjustment to remove bias in observational studies, Biometrics. (1973) 185-203. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[33] | P.R. Rosenbaum, D.B. Rubin, Constructing a control group using multivariate matched sampling methods that incorporate the propensity score, Am. Stat. 39 (1985) 33-38. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[34] | J. Bauchet, E.A. Undurraga, V. Reyes-García, J.R. Behrman, R.A. Godoy, Conditional cash transfers for primary education: Which children are left out?, World Dev. 105 (2018) 1-12. | ||
In article | View Article PubMed | ||
[35] | L.T. Giang, C.V. Nguyen, How would cash transfers improve child welfare in Viet Nam?, Child. Youth Serv. Rev. 82 (2017) 87-98. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[36] | P. Givord, Méthodes économétriques pour l’évaluation de politiques publiques, Econ. Previs. (2014) 1-28. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[37] | A. Chong, M. Yáñez-Pagans, Not so fast! Cash transfers can increase child labor: Evidence for Bolivia, Econ. Lett. 179 (2019) 57-61. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[38] | J. Choi, M. Lee, Relaxing conditions for local average treatment effect in fuzzy regression discontinuity, Econ. Lett. 173 (2018) 47-50. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[39] | J.D. Angrist, G.W. Imbens, D.B. Rubin, Identification of causal effects using instrumental variables, J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 91 (1996) 444-455. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[40] | J. Hahn, J. Hausman, Weak instruments: Diagnosis and cures in empirical econometrics, Am. Econ. Rev. 93 (2003) 118-125. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
Published with license by Science and Education Publishing, Copyright © 2021 Marouane IKIRA and Abdeljaouad EZZRARI
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License. To view a copy of this license, visit
https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/
[1] | T.W. Schultz, Investment in human capital, Am. Econ. Rev. 51 (1961) 1-17. | ||
In article | |||
[2] | G.S. Becker, Human capital: A theoretical and empirical analysis, with special reference to education, University of Chicago press, 2009. | ||
In article | |||
[3] | M. Ravallion, Q. Wodon, Does Child Labor Displace Schooling? Evidence on Behavioral Responses to an Enrollment Subsidy. Policy Research Working Papers No. 2116., (1999). | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[4] | A. de Janvry, F. Finan, E. Sadoulet, How Effective are Educational Subsidies Programs for the Rural Poor? Progresa in Mexico, ARE Univ. Calif. Berkeley. (2001). | ||
In article | |||
[5] | E. Skoufias, S.W. Parker, J.R. Behrman, C. Pessino, Conditional cash transfers and their impact on child work and schooling: Evidence from the progresa program in mexico [with comments], Economia. 2 (2001) 45-96. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[6] | K. Kilburn, S. Handa, G. Angeles, P. Mvula, M. Tsoka, Short-term impacts of an unconditional cash transfer program on child schooling: Experimental evidence from Malawi, Econ. Educ. Rev. 59 (2017) 63-80. | ||
In article | View Article PubMed | ||
[7] | O. Attanasio, E. Fitzsimons, A. Gomez, The impact of a conditional education subsidy on school enrolment in Colombia, (2005). | ||
In article | |||
[8] | X. V Del Carpio, N. V Loayza, T. Wada, The impact of conditional cash transfers on the amount and type of child labor, World Dev. 80 (2016) 33-47. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[9] | N. Benhassine, F. Devoto, E. Duflo, P. Dupas, V. Pouliquen, Turning a shove into a nudge? A “labeled cash transfer” for education, Am. Econ. J. Econ. Policy. 7 (2015) 86-125. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[10] | J. Gazeaud, C. Ricard, Cash Transfers and School Performances: New Evidence from Morocco, 2020. | ||
In article | |||
[11] | E. V Edmonds, N. Schady, Poverty alleviation and child labor, Am. Econ. J. Econ. Policy. 4 (2012) 100-124. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[12] | A. Hidayatina, A. Garces-Ozanne, Can cash transfers mitigate child labour? Evidence from Indonesia’s cash transfer programme for poor students in Java, World Dev. Perspect. 15 (2019) 1. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[13] | P. De Vreyer, Une analyse économétrique de la demande d’éducation en Côte-d’Ivoire, Rev. Econ. Dev. 1 (1993) 49-79. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[14] | C. Buchmann, Family structure, parental perceptions, and child labor in Kenya: What factors determine who is enrolled in school?, Soc. Forces. 78 (2000) 1349-1378. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[15] | S. Jimerson, B. Egeland, L.A. Sroufe, B. Carlson, A prospective longitudinal study of high school dropouts examining multiple predictors across development, J. Sch. Psychol. 38 (2000) 525-549. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[16] | P. Glewwe, Schools and skills in developing countries: education policies and socioeconomic outcomes, J. Econ. Lit. 40 (2002) 436-482. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[17] | J. Vinas-Forcade, C. Mels, M. Valcke, I. Derluyn, Beyond academics: Dropout prevention summer school programs in the transition to secondary education, Int. J. Educ. Dev. 70 (2019) 102087. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[18] | Y. Itzhaki, H. Itzhaky, Y.B. Yablon, The contribution of parental and societal conditional regard to adjustment of high school dropouts, J. Adolesc. 62 (2018) 151-161. | ||
In article | View Article PubMed | ||
[19] | P. Glewwe, A.L. Kassouf, The impact of the Bolsa Escola/Familia conditional cash transfer program on enrollment, dropout rates and grade promotion in Brazil, J. Dev. Econ. 97 (2012) 505-517. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[20] | F. No, K. Taniguchi, Y. Hirakawa, School dropout at the basic education level in rural Cambodia: Identifying its causes through longitudinal survival analysis, Int. J. Educ. Dev. 49 (2016) 215-224. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[21] | H.G. Jacoby, E. Skoufias, Risk, financial markets, and human capital in a developing country, Rev. Econ. Stud. 64 (1997) 311-335. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[22] | M.N.U. Din, H. Dad, J. Iqbal, S.S.A. Shah, M.I. Niazi, Causes of male dropout rate in Pakistan, J. Coll. Teach. Learn. 8 (2011) 37-42. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[23] | A. Diagne, Pourquoi les enfants africains quittent-ils l’école? Un modèle hiérarchique multinomial des abandons dans l’éducation primaire au Sénégal, Actual. Econ. 86 (2010) 319-354. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[24] | R.W. Rumberger, Dropping out, Harvard University Press, 2011. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[25] | S. Gao, M. Yang, X. Wang, W. Min, S. Rozelle, Peer relations and dropout behavior: Evidence from junior high school students in northwest rural China, Int. J. Educ. Dev. 65 (2019) 134-143. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[26] | O. Attanasio, E. Fitzsimons, A. Gomez, M.I. Gutierrez, C. Meghir, A. Mesnard, Children’s schooling and work in the presence of a conditional cash transfer program in rural Colombia, Econ. Dev. Cult. Change. 58 (2010) 181-210. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[27] | K.A. Gee, Reducing child labour through conditional cash transfers: Evidence from nicaragua’s red de protección social, Dev. Policy Rev. 28 (2010) 711-732. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[28] | J. De Hoop, J. Friedman, E. Kandpal, F. Rosati, Child schooling and child work in the presence of a partial education subsidy, The World Bank, 2017. | ||
In article | View Article PubMed | ||
[29] | A.B. Gouzi, N. El Aoufi, La non-scolarisation au Maroc Une analyse en termes de coût d’opportunité, Crit. Économique. (2007). | ||
In article | |||
[30] | A. V Banerjee, R. Hanna, G.E. Kreindler, B.A. Olken, Debunking the stereotype of the lazy welfare recipient: Evidence from cash transfer programs, World Bank Res. Obs. 32 (2017) 155-184. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[31] | P.R. Rosenbaum, D.B. Rubin, The central role of the propensity score in observational studies for causal effects, Biometrika. 70 (1983) 41-55. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[32] | D.B. Rubin, The use of matched sampling and regression adjustment to remove bias in observational studies, Biometrics. (1973) 185-203. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[33] | P.R. Rosenbaum, D.B. Rubin, Constructing a control group using multivariate matched sampling methods that incorporate the propensity score, Am. Stat. 39 (1985) 33-38. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[34] | J. Bauchet, E.A. Undurraga, V. Reyes-García, J.R. Behrman, R.A. Godoy, Conditional cash transfers for primary education: Which children are left out?, World Dev. 105 (2018) 1-12. | ||
In article | View Article PubMed | ||
[35] | L.T. Giang, C.V. Nguyen, How would cash transfers improve child welfare in Viet Nam?, Child. Youth Serv. Rev. 82 (2017) 87-98. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[36] | P. Givord, Méthodes économétriques pour l’évaluation de politiques publiques, Econ. Previs. (2014) 1-28. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[37] | A. Chong, M. Yáñez-Pagans, Not so fast! Cash transfers can increase child labor: Evidence for Bolivia, Econ. Lett. 179 (2019) 57-61. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[38] | J. Choi, M. Lee, Relaxing conditions for local average treatment effect in fuzzy regression discontinuity, Econ. Lett. 173 (2018) 47-50. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[39] | J.D. Angrist, G.W. Imbens, D.B. Rubin, Identification of causal effects using instrumental variables, J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 91 (1996) 444-455. | ||
In article | View Article | ||
[40] | J. Hahn, J. Hausman, Weak instruments: Diagnosis and cures in empirical econometrics, Am. Econ. Rev. 93 (2003) 118-125. | ||
In article | View Article | ||