New Proxy of Financial Development and Economic Growth in Medium-Income Countries: A Bootstrap Panel...

Khalil Mhadhbi

  Open Access OPEN ACCESS  Peer Reviewed PEER-REVIEWED

New Proxy of Financial Development and Economic Growth in Medium-Income Countries: A Bootstrap Panel Granger Causality Analysis

Khalil Mhadhbi

Faculty of Economic Sciences and Management of Tunis

Abstract

This paper examines the causal relationship between financial development and economic growth for 27 medium-income countries in the period 1970 to 2012. We develop a new proxy for financial development that refers to the input of real resources into the financial system and apply the panel bootstrapped approach to Granger causality. The results show, for three countries the findings support strong evidence on supply-leading hypothesis which implies that financial development induces economic growth and for six countries the findings support strong evidence on demand-following. Our results confirm for twenty one countries suggesting that their financial development does not depend on economic growth.

Cite this article:

  • Mhadhbi, Khalil. "New Proxy of Financial Development and Economic Growth in Medium-Income Countries: A Bootstrap Panel Granger Causality Analysis." American Journal of Applied Mathematics and Statistics 2.4 (2014): 185-192.
  • Mhadhbi, K. (2014). New Proxy of Financial Development and Economic Growth in Medium-Income Countries: A Bootstrap Panel Granger Causality Analysis. American Journal of Applied Mathematics and Statistics, 2(4), 185-192.
  • Mhadhbi, Khalil. "New Proxy of Financial Development and Economic Growth in Medium-Income Countries: A Bootstrap Panel Granger Causality Analysis." American Journal of Applied Mathematics and Statistics 2, no. 4 (2014): 185-192.

Import into BibTeX Import into EndNote Import into RefMan Import into RefWorks

1. Introduction

Economists hold opinions of the role of finance in economic growth and the developed theoretical literature mirrors the divisions. The question of whether or not financial development affects economic activity has attracted a lot of attention in previous and current research (Kirkpatrick, 2000; Ang, 2008; Murinde, 2012). Bagehot (1873) and Hicks (1969) argued that financial system played a critical role in igniting industrialization in England by facilitating the mobilization of capital for “immense works.” Schumpeter (1934) emphasized the importance of the banking system in economic growth and highlighted circumstances when banks can actively spur innovation and future growth by identifying and funding productive investments. With the contributions of McKinnon (1973) and Shaw (1973), the relationship between financial development and economic growth has been an important issue of debate, and during the last thirty years these studies have fostered a fresh research interest in this relationship. Recent empirical studies, however, offer contradictory evidence (Kaminsky and Reinhart, 1999; Deidda and Fattouh, 2002; Wachtel, 2003; Favara, 2003; Rousseau and Wachtel, 2011and Arcand et al., 2012).

In addition, the direction of causality still remains divisive. In summary, three schools of thought are identifiable in the extant literature: supply-leading response school of thought which argues that financial development leads to economic growth pioneered by Schumpeter (1911) and confirmed by notable studies such as Rajan and Zingales (1998), Levine et al., (2000) and Bittencourt (2012); demand-leading school of thought supported by studies such as Odhiambo (2004), Liang and Teng (2006) and Zang and Kim (2007) and Odhiambo (2008) which argues that growth leads to financial development; and bidirectional school of thought grounded by the studies such as Wood (1993), Demetriades and Hussein (1996), Akinboade (1998), Luintel and Khan (1999), Rousseau and Vuthipadadorn (2005) and Apergis et al., (2007) which submits that there is a bidirectional causality between financial development and economic growth. This shows that a consensus on the role of financial development in the process of economic growth does not so far exist.

Unfortunately, there is no simple procedure to determine which view is empirically adequate – not even one that would rule out some views as obviously false. First, the factors that govern economic growth admittedly include many others besides financial development, and interactions among them are likely to prevail. Second, mutual causation, which in economic growth may be the rule rather than the exception, makes it difficult, if not impossible, to rule out a specific hypothesis. Third, the existing data on financial development are plagued by poor reliability and dubious validity. Thus, the existing econometric studies do not really rule out any of the main hypotheses; significant results can be cited for any of them.

Consequently, the current verdict on the relationship between financial development and economic growth and their causality has remained inconclusive. However, the discussion focuses on measures of financial development, which must move literature because most authors only analyze an approach that from the outputs and the same database published by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank. Accordingly, it is logical to find almost the same results. In addition, what might be an adequate financial system at one time or in one social, institutional and economic environment may be outright detrimental at another time or in other environments. In other words: there may be various structural shifts or breaks which further complicate identification of causal relationships.

The economic historians are able to give convincing examples for all possibilities of causality outlined above. There is, obviously, need for further research. This paper contributes to the existing literature in several aspects. First, a new, resource-based (rather than monetary) proxy variable for financial development will be introduced. This new proxy will be used to investigate the possibility of Granger causality between financial development and economic growth. Second, The sample adopted for the dataset is wider than other contributions based on the panel approach and includes 27 medium-income countries{1} from 1970–2012. Third, this study is one of the few researches use the bootstrap panel Granger causality testing approach of Kónya (2006) that allows testing for causality on each individual country separably by accounting for dependence across countries.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 gives a description of sample, the new proxy for financial activity and economic growth. Section 3 outlines the econometric methodology employed. Section 4 discusses the empirical findings. Finally, Section 5 concludes.

2. Sample and Data

The annual data used in this study cover the period from 1970-2012 for 27 medium-income countries. Consistent with theoretical specifications and previous studies (Demetriades and Hussein, 1996; Arestis et al., 2001; Beck and Levine, 2004, Odhiambo, 2010), we define economic development as the logarithm of real GDP per capita. The sample excluding countries that are very small (less than one million), countries with centrally planned economies{2} during the period 1970-2012, countries where oil exports constituted over 20% of GDP in 1995, and countries with civil wars claiming a death toll exceeding 2.5% of total population during 1970-2012. The exclusion of these countries in the sample is justified by the fact that it is unreasonable to run regressions across countries that are fundamentally different from the usual conditions (Harberger, 1998).

2.1. A New Proxy for Financial Development

One of the most important issues in assessing the relationship between financial development and economic growth is how to obtain a satisfactory empirical measure of financial development. An increase in financial instruments and the foundation of these instruments more commonly available in a country is defined as financial development. Various measures have been used in the literature to proxy for the “level of financial development”. For instance, the proportion of the financial sector to GDP is defined as financial depth (Depth). However, due to instability and differences in definition, the choice of an appropriate monetary aggregate raises a serious problem (Khan and Senhadji, 2000). Private shows the effectiveness of the financial system towards the private sector. Bank shows the importance of assets of deposit banks, compared to those of the central bank. Nowadays, credit to the private sector is seen as an inefficient allocation and detrimental to the sustainable growth achievement. To solve problems related to these measures that reflect the monetization and the allocation of credit, an innovative approach has a specific branch within the empirical literature (La Porta et al., 1998, 2008). This approach refers to variables concerning the origin of a country's legal system and, more bureaucratic and political characteristics as the instrumental variables to the the traditional measure of financial development. The problems of bias and convergence of the estimators are therefore corrected. However, these instruments are usually very rough qualitative variables. A classification by legal origin, which refers to the socio-economic and political constitution of a country, makes the possibility of evaluating the financial sector's contribution to growth during recent decades very limited.

Finally, some researchers attempt to identify the structural features of the financial system. These contributions (Goldsmith, 1969 and 1987; Bhattarcharyay, 1988; Clague et al., 1997 and Ergungor, 2008) refer to different ratios of currency or credit aggregates (eg, M2/M1 or credit of the central bank in the private credit), while researchers such as Beck, Demirguç-Kunt and Levine{3} have constructed a large database of national characteristics and institutional performance indicators, referring to the various financial institutions. These features may eventually help classify financial systems from the fundamental theory but empirically unclear. While this distinction of countries according to a financial system based on banks versus market-based or oriented versus the rights of creditors facing the debtor's rights, is encouraging as regards the possibility to specify the nature of link between finance and growth. This research is still at the consolidation of data and resulting classifications.

We leave the boundaries of those measures in the empirical literature and the work of Graff (2001, 2002 and 2005) on the growth-finance relationship, proposing a new proxy measure for financial development based on the inputs of the financial system. The construction of the new variable for financial development is motivated by the interest in obtaining a reasonably reliable and comparable quantification of the proportion of societal resources devoted to the financial system. Even if the intention has a certain resemblance to the basic argument of transaction costs and institutional economics (Williamson, 1985; North, 1990), namely, that the overall transaction costs are far from negligible and that financial institutions are a major response to this problem. Instead, we consider that the amount of resources devoted to the functioning of these institutions as a reliable indicator of the effort to control transaction costs (and, frictions and market failures due to asymmetric information that is tempered by the financial system).

This measurement is the first principal component of a set of different indicators (For more details on the database, refer to Appendix.) for financial activity. While monetary indicators, such as Depth, are very difficult to compare over time and space because of the diversity and institutional change. Our proxy is likely to be less sensitive to changes in the institutional regulations and national and international shocks, but to capture rather stable characteristics of a given economy’s structure. In addition, it is well known that monetary indicators are leading indicators of business cycles. Therefore, these variables are less endogenous inputs to current economic activity that traditional variables of financial development.

In terms of their approximate validity in quantitative conception of financial activity, the financial system’s share in GDP, that is to say, the factor incomes generated in the financial sector, is probably the best indicator. More specifically, the share of the financial system in GDP consists of wages and the labor markets are characterized by the optimality of wages fixed by the market. This is based on equality between wages and marginal productivity of labor. The sector's share is valued at conditions that are very close to what most economists consider appropriate. Following this line of reasoning, the only flaw is to point to the observation that in the real world factor markets are frequently far from resulting in market clearing prices, so that some reservation is called for.

The second indicator is the number of banks and branches per capita, which gives an idea about the degree to which a country's population has access to financial services. Obviously, the validity of this indicator is weakened by differences in the dispersion of a country’s population over its territory. In addition to this, technical progress and financial innovations, such as, telephone and Internet banking have made the accessibility of a bank office obsolete for many financial interactions and services. Thus, although this measure indicates a decline in financial development in most developed countries in recent years is the result of innovations in the banking sector and thus a sign of progress rather than a decline. Indeed, Table 1 shows the first signs of stabilization or even a fall in the number of banks and branches by one of the active population, which could indicate a structural break, but only after 1990. Considering these arguments, the use of this indicator for recent years in highly developed countries may cause a problem. However, since our analysis refers to the period 1970-2012 and covers a wide sample of countries.

Table 1. Banks and branches per 100,000 labor forces, by level of development

For a study on the relationship finance-growth in a cross-sample of countries covering thirty or forty years, despite all the adjustments and reservations, due to data quality indicators are considered far from satisfactory. Thus, these variables can be transformed in a way to make these measures reasonably reliable, valid and complete, to reflect the concept of ‘resources for finance'. The procedure is currently chosen to determine the common variance of the three indicators, using principal component analysis (PCA). If the operating costs of the financial system are reasonably well represented by the first principal component this component can serve as a valid proxy variable for financial development. The PCA is based on the variance of specific variables and can extract a minimum of factors that explain the largest number of specific variance. To approach this goal, a technical requirement must be satisfied: the dummy variables must be measured independently. This condition is satisfied, because our three variables for the size of the financial system are derived from different databases. The PCA is a technique that aims to identify groups of quantitative variables strongly linked. This group is called 'component'. Variables (in our case, the three new inputs of financial activity) belonging to the same component are strongly linked represent a single concept 'financial development'. Instead, variables not linked they do not measure the same concept and are not part of the same component.

Table 2. A financial development proxy from principal component analysis

Practically, to prepare raw series, the three variables (number of banks and branches per capita, weighted share of manpower employed in the financial system, share of the financial system in GDP) were carefully screened for obvious errors and incompatibilities. Subsequently, PCA (We conducted a PCA using SPSS (Statistical Package for the Social Sciences).) was applied to a set of observations arising from a matrix of 1134 × 3. The PCA results are shown in Table 2.

Table 2 reveals that the principal component extraction is quite well done. It reduces the data and gives us a first principal component representing 75% of the overall variance (a total of 70% of variance explained is generally considered acceptable). In addition, the variance is explained for the second and third principal component accounts for only 17.9% and 7.4% respectively. All loadings are high (0.87 for banks per capita, 0.93 for the share of finance in GDP and 0.81 for the share of manpower in financial sector), indicating that the expected three-dimensional structure of the three variables is in fact well represented only by the first principal component. Therefore, in what follows, the individual scores for this component are taken as proxy of financial development (FD) for future analysis. We can therefore proceed to a new variable defined, which assigns a specific value for financial development. This indicator is defined for the 27 countries in our sample, across 42 time points (n = 1134, μ = 0 and σ = 1).

3. Econometric Methodology

The choice of a suitable method allowing for the analysis of causality for panel data requires the assessment of cross-sectional dependence. If cross-sectional dependence exists, the seemingly unrelated regressions (SUR) are more efficient then the ordinary least-squares (OLS) (Zellner, 1962). Kónya (2006) proposed a method to account for both the cross-sectional dependence and the heterogeneity. It is based on SUR systems and Wald tests with country specific bootstrap critical values and eanbles to test for Granger-causality on each individual panel member separately, by taking into account the possible contemporaneous correlation across countries. Given its generality, we will implement this last approach in this paper.

Our empirical methodology is carried out in two steps. First, we devote our attention to preliminary analysis to investigate cross-section dependence. In the second step, based on the results from preliminary analysis we apply an appropriate panel causality method, which is able to represent cross-section features our panel data set to do the test. In what follows, we briefly outline the econometric methods.

3.1. Tests of Cross-Sectional Dependence

The first step in analyzing panel data Granger causality is testing for cross-sectional dependence. Kónya (2006) and Kar et al., (2010), to investigate the existence of cross- sectional dependence we employ four different cross-sectional dependence test statistics: Lagrange multiplier test statistic (LM) of Breusch and Pagan (1980), two tests statistic of Pesaran (2004), one based on Lagrange multiplier (CDLM) and the other based on the pair-wise correlation coefficients (CD) and test of Pesaran et al., (2008) (LMadj). Pesaran et al., (2008) concluded that the CD test has an important drawback, namely it will lack power in certain situations where the population average pair-wise correlations are zero, although the underlying individual population pair-wise correlations are non-zero. Pesaran et al., (2008) proposed a bias-adjusted test, which is a modified version of the LM test, by using the exact mean and variance of the LM statistic.

The Lagrange multiplier test statistic for cross-sectional dependence of Breusch and Pagan (1980) is given by:

(1)

Where is the estimated correlation coefficient among the residuals obtained from individual OLS estimations. Under the null hypothesis of no cross-sectional dependency with a fixed N (number of cross-sections) and time period T → ∞, the statistic has chi-square asymptotic distribution with N(N −1) / 2 degrees of freedom. It is important to note that the LM test is applicable with N relatively small and T sufficiently large. This drawback was attempted to be solved by Pesaran (2004) by the following scaled version of the LM test:

(2)

Under the null hypothesis of no cross-sectional dependence with T → ∞ and N → ∞, this test statistic has the standard normal distribution. Though CDLM is applicable even for N and T large, it is likely to exhibit substantial size distortions when N is large relative to T. The shortcomings of the LM and the CDLM tests clearly show a need for a cross-sectional dependency test that can be applicable with large N and small T. In that respect, Pesaran (2004) proposed the following test for cross-sectional dependence CD:

(3)

However, in some cases that the population average pair-wise correlations are zero, the CD test is lacking power, although the underlying individual population pair-wise correlations are non-zero (Pesaran et al., 2008). Furthermore, when the mean of the factor loadings is zero in the cross-sectional dimension, the CD test can not reject the null hypothesis in stationary dynamic (Sarafidis and Robertson, 2009). In order to solve this problem, Pesaran et al. (2008) raises a modified version of the LM test based on the exact mean and variance of the LM statistic. This bias-adjusted LM test is:

(4)

Where μTij and v2Tij are respectively the exact mean and variance of (T-k)ρ2ij provided in Pesaran et al., (2008 p. 108). Pesaran et al., (2008) showed that under the null hypothesis of no cross-sectional dependence with T → ∞ first followed by N → ∞, the statistics LMadj follow an asymptotic standard normal distribution.

3.2. Panel Causality Test

The panel causality approach by Kónya (2006) that examine the relation-ship between Y and FD can be formulated as follows:

(5)

In these formulas, index i refers to the country (i = 1, ..., N), t to the time period (t = 1, ..., T) the period, s the lag, and ly1, lFD1, ly2 and lFD2 indicate the lag lengths. The error terms, ε1,i,t and ε2,i,t are supposed to be white-noises (i.e. they have zero means, constant variances and are individually serially uncorrelated) that may be correlated with each other for a given country, but not across countries (ε1,i,t and ε2,i,t are correlated when there is feedback between FD and Y, i.e. in the non-reduced form of (1), called structural VAR, yt depends on FDt and/or FDt depends on yt. For a proof see Enders (2004, p. 266).).

In this study, we consider bivariate systems, and we apply it in our context to economic growth and financial development. With respect to system (5) for instance, in country i there is one-way Granger-causality running from FD to Y if in the first equation not all β2,i’s are zero but in the second all γ1,i’s are zero; there is one-way Granger-causality from Y to FD if in the first equation all γ1,i’s are zero but in the second not all β2,i’s are zero; there is two-way Granger-causality between Y and FD if neither all β2,i’s nor all γ1,i’s are zero; and there is no Granger-causality between Y and FD if all β2,i’s and γ1,i’s are zero (Chang et al., 2013).

Since for a given country the two equations in (5) contain the same pre-determined, i.e. lagged exogenous and endogenous variables, the OLS estimators of the parameters are consistent and asymptotically efficient. This suggests that the 2N equations in the system can be estimated one-by-one, in any preferred order. Then, instead of N VAR systems in (5), we can consider the following two sets of equations:

(6)

and

(7)

Compared to (5), each equation in (6), and also in (7), has different predetermined variables. The only possible link among individual regressions is contemporaneous correlation within the systems. Therefore, system 6 and 7 must be estimated by (SUR) procedure to take into account contemporaneous correlation within the systems (in presence of contemporaneous correlation the SUR estimator is more efficient than the OLS estimator). Following Kónya (2006), we use country specific bootstrap Wald critical values to implement Granger causality. This procedure (For the details and exposition of the estimation and testing procedures, see Konya (2006), Kar et al. (2011), and Tekin (2012).) has several advantages. Firstly, it does not assume that the panel is homogeneous, so it is possible to test for Granger-causality on each individual panel member separately. However, since contemporaneous correlation is allowed across countries, it makes possible to exploit the extra information provided by the panel data setting. Therefore, country specific bootstrap critical values are generated. Secondly, this approach does not require pretesting for unit roots and cointegration, though it still requires the specification of the lag structure. This is an important feature since the unit-root and cointegration tests in general suffer from low power, and different tests often lead to contradictory outcomes. Thirdly, this panel Granger causality approach allows the researcher to detect for how many and for which members of the panel there exists one-way Granger-causality, two-way Granger-causality or no Granger-causality.

Because the results of the causality test may be sensitive to the lag structure, determining the optimal lag length is crucial for robustness of findings (Chang and Hsieh, 2012). As indicated by Kónya (2006), the selection of optimal lag structure is important because the causality test results may depend critically on the lag structure. In general, both too few and too many lags may cause problems. Too few lags mean that some important variables are omitted from the model and this specification error will usually cause bias in the retained regression coefficients, leading to incorrect conclusions. On the other hand, too many lags waste observations and this specification error will usually increase the standard errors of the estimated coefficients, making the results less precise. For a relatively large panel, equation and variable with varying lag structure would lead to an increase in the computational burden substantially. Following Kónya (2006), we decided to allow for different lags in each system but did not allow for different lags across countries. Assuming that the number of lags ranges from 1 to 4, we estimated all equations and used the Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) and Schwartz Criterion (SC) to determine the optimal (The combinations which minimize the AIC and SC.) solution defined as:

Where W stands for estimated residual covariance matrix, N is the number of equations, q is the number of coefficients per equation, T is the sample size, all in system k = 1, 2. Occasionally, these two criteria select different lag lengths.

4. Results and Discussions

As outlined earlier, testing for cross-sectional dependency in a panel causality study is crucial for selecting the appropriate estimator. To investigate the existence of cross-section dependence, we carried out four different test (LM, CDLM, CD, LMadj ) and illustrate results in Table 4. The results show that all the four tests reject the null of no cross-sectional dependence across the members of the panel at 1% level of significance; this implies that the SUR method is more appropriate than the country-by-country OLS estimation. This finding implies that a strong economic links exist between sample countries. These findings show that a shock which occurred in one country of the sample will be transmitted to other countries.

The existence of cross-sectional dependence in these countries means that it is justified to use the Bootstrap Panel Granger Causality method in Kónya (2006). For each system of equations the number of lags was chosen according to the AIC and SC criterion (We used the AIC criterion to compare the specifications with and without a linear trend. Finally, we constructed SUR with one lag and without a linear trend.). Additionally, specifications incorporating deterministic trend were taken into account. The results from the bootstrap (Following the original paper of Kónya (2006) and several others, e.g. Nazlioglu et. al., (2011), we used 10000 replications in the procedure. Andrews and Buchinsky (2001) provide an exact method of evaluating the adequacy of the chosen number of replications.) panel Granger causality (The TSP routine written by László Kónya was used to obtain the results for the panel Granger causality test. We are grateful to László Kónya for sharing his codes.) analysis are reported in Table 4.

Our empirical results show that the Granger causality from FD to economic growth exists in Argentina, Brazil and South Africa, but not in the other twenty four countries and the feedback hypothesis for Guatemala, Iran, Jamaica, Morocco, Panama and Thailand, but not in the other twenty one countries.

Some points are worth noting based on the results given above. Firstly, compared to the number of countries considered, Granger non causality in either direction can be rejected relatively rarely. Secondly, for three counties the findings support strong evidence on supply-leading hypothesis which implies that financial development induces economic growth. On the other hand, for six countries the findings support strong evidence on demand-following.

Table 4. Results for panel causality: Wald tests with bootstrapping, mlY = mlFD = 1

5. Conclusion

In this paper we have studied the possibility of Granger causality between financial development and economic growth in twenty seven medium-income countries from 1970 to 2012. It is the fact that there is a vast diverse figure in terms of financial development in these countries. Some of them have a relatively developed financial sector but others are not.

We developed a new proxy for financial development from three financial development indicators using principal component analysis and applied to a panel causality analysis which accounts for cross-country dependency. This approach has two advantages. On the one hand, it does not assume that the panel is homogeneous, so it is possible to perform Granger causality tests on each individual panel member separately. However, since contemporaneous correlation is allowed across countries, it makes possible to exploit the extra information provided by the panel data setting. On the other hand, this approach does not require pretesting for unit roots and cointegration, though it still requires the specification of the lag structure. This is an important feature since the unit-root and cointegration tests in general suffer from low power. Different tests often lead to contradictory outcomes, so the conclusions drawn from them are usually conditional on some more or less arbitrary decisions made by the researcher. The empirical results indicate that out of the twenty seven countries studied we find support for the ‘demand following’ hypothesis in only in six countries and for the ‘supply leading’ hypothesis in three countries. Finally, the financial development does not depend on economic growth, but is enhanced by other factors in twenty one countries.

References

[1]  Akinboade, O.A, Financial development and economic growth in Botswana: a test for causality. Savings and Development. 1998, 223, 331-348.
In article      
 
[2]  Andrews, D. W. K., Buchinsky, M. Evaluation of a Three-step Method for Choosing the Number of Bootstrap Repetitions, Journal of Econometrics, 2001, 103, 345-386.
In article      CrossRef
 
[3]  Ang, J.B. Survey of recent developments in the literature of finance and growth. J. Econ. Surv, 2008, 22 3, 536-576.
In article      CrossRef
 
[4]  Apergis, N., Filippidis, I., Economidou, C, Financial deepening and economic growth linkages: a panel data analysis. Review of World Economics, 2007, 1431, 179-198.
In article      CrossRef
 
[5]  Arcand J., Berkes, E., Panizza, U, Too Much Finance? International Monetary Fund.Research Department, 2012.
In article      
 
[6]  Arestis, P., Demetriades, P., Luintel, K, Financial Development and Economic Growth: The Role of Stock Markets. Journal of Money, Credit, & Banking, 2001, 33, 16-41.
In article      CrossRef
 
[7]  Bagehot, W, Lombard Street. Homewood, IL: Richard D. Irwin. 1962.
In article      
 
[8]  Barro, R., Lee, JW, International measures of schooling years and schooling quality. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 1996. 86: 218-223.
In article      
 
[9]  Beck, T., Levine, R., Loayza, N, Finance and the sources of growth. Journal of Financial Economics, 2000, 58, 261-300.
In article      CrossRef
 
[10]  Beck, T. Levine, R, Stock Markets, Banks, and Growth: Panel Evidence. Journal of Banking and Finance, 2004, 283, 423-442.
In article      CrossRef
 
[11]  Bhattarcharyay, BN, Development of financial infrastructure: an international comparison. Savings and Development, 1988, 12, 307-319.
In article      
 
[12]  Bittencourt, M, Financial development and economic growth in Latin America: is schumpeter right? Journal of Policy Modeling; 2012, 343, 341-355.
In article      CrossRef
 
[13]  Breusch, T Pagan, A, The LM test and its Application to Model Specification in Econometrics. Review of Economic Studies, 1980, 47, 239-254
In article      CrossRef
 
[14]  Chang, TY., Hsieh, WK, Does Insurance Activity Promote Output? Further Evidence Based on Bootstrap Panel Granger Causality Test. Working paper Feng Chia University, 2012.
In article      
 
[15]  Chang, TY., Simo-Kengne, BD., Gupta, R, The Causal Relationship between House Prices and Economic Growth in the Nine Provinces of South Africa: Evidence from Panel-Granger Causality Tests. Working Paper. University of Pretoria, 2013.
In article      
 
[16]  Clague, C., Keefer, P., Knack, S., Mancur, O, Institutions and economic performance, in: C. Clague Ed. Institutions and Economic Development, 1997, pp. 67-90 Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press.
In article      
 
[17]  Deidda, L., Fattouh, B, Non-linearity between finance and growth. Economics Letters, 2002, 743, 339-345.
In article      CrossRef
 
[18]  Demetriades, P.O., Hussein, K.A, Does financial development cause economic growth? Time series evidence from 16 countries. Journal of Development Economics, 1996, 512, 87-411.
In article      
 
[19]  Demirgüç-Kunt, A., Levine, R, Bank-based and market-based financial systems, cross-country comparisons. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, 1999. No. 2143, Washington DC.
In article      
 
[20]  Enders, W, Applied Econometric Time Series, 2nd ed., Wiley, 2004.
In article      
 
[21]  Ergungor, EO, . International Review of Economics & Finance, 2008, 17, 292-305.
In article      CrossRef
 
[22]  Favara, G, An Empirical Reassessment of the Relationship between Finance and Growth. Washington, DC: IMF. 2003.
In article      
 
[23]  Goldsmith, RW, Financial Structure and Development. New Haven: Yale University Press. 1969.
In article      
 
[24]  Goldsmith, RW, Premodern Financial Systems. A Historical Comparative Study Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 1987.
In article      CrossRef
 
[25]  Graff, M, Socio-Economic Factors and the Finance-Growth Nexus. The European Journal of Finance 11, 183-205.
In article      CrossRef
 
[26]  Graff, M, 2001. Economies, political, and social conditions affecting the influence of financial activity on economic growth. Paper submission to SPIE 7 Annual conference. 2005.
In article      
 
[27]  Graff, M, Causal Links Between Financial Activity and Economic Growth: Empirical Evidence from a Cross-Country Analysis, 1970-1990. Bulletin of Economic Research, 2002, 54, 119-133.
In article      CrossRef
 
[28]  Harberger, AC, A Vision of the Growth Process. American Economic Review, 1998, 88: 1-33.
In article      
 
[29]  Hicks, J, A theory of economic history. Oxford: Clarendon Press. 1969.
In article      
 
[30]  Kaminsky, GL., Reinhart, CM, The twin crises: the causes of banking and balance-of- payments problems. The American Economic Review Evanston, 1999, 8903, 473-500.
In article      CrossRef
 
[31]  Kar, M., Nazlogluc, S., Agr, H, Financial development and economic growth nexus in the MENA countries: Bootstrap panel granger causality analysis. Economic Modelling, 2010. 28, 685-693.
In article      CrossRef
 
[32]  Khan, M. S., Senhadji, A, Threshold Effects in the Relationship between Inflation and Growth. IMF Working Paper, 2000, No. 00/110
In article      
 
[33]  Kirkpatrick, C, Financial Development, Economic Growth and Poverty Reduction. Mahboob Ul Haq Memorial Lecture at 16th AGM of PSDE, January 2000.
In article      
 
[34]  Kónya, L, Exports and growth: Granger causality analysis on OECD Countries with a panel data approach. Economic Modelling, 2006. 23, 978-992.
In article      CrossRef
 
[35]  La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A, Capital market and legal institutions. NBER Working Paper, 1998, n 6727.
In article      
 
[36]  La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F., Shleifer, A, The Economic Consequences of Legal Origins. Journal of Economic Literature, 2008, 46, 285-332.
In article      CrossRef
 
[37]  Levine, R., Loayza, N., Beck, T, Financial intermediation and growth: causality and causes. Journal of Monetary Economics, 2000, 46, 31-77.
In article      CrossRef
 
[38]  Liang, Q., Teng, J.Z, Financial development and economic growth: evidence from China. China Economic Review, 2006, 174, 395-411.
In article      CrossRef
 
[39]  Luintel, R., Khan, M, A quantitative re-assessment of the finance-growth nexus: evidence from a multivariate VAR. Journal of Development Economics, 1999, 60, 381-405.
In article      CrossRef
 
[40]  McKinnon, R.I,. Money and capital in economic development. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.
In article      
 
[41]  Murinde, V, 2012. Financial development and economic growth: global and African experience. J. Afr. Econ, 197, 21 Suppl. 1, i10-i56.
In article      CrossRef
 
[42]  Nazlioglu, S., Lebe, F., Kayhan, S, Nuclear Energy Consumption and Economic Growth in OECD Countries: Cross-sectionally Dependent Heterogeneous Panel Causality Analysis. Energy Policy, 2011, 39, 6615-6621.
In article      CrossRef
 
[43]  North, DC, Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 1990.
In article      CrossRef
 
[44]  Odhiambo, N.M, Is financial development still a spur to economic growth? A causal evidence from South Africa. Savings and Development, 2004, 28, 47-62.
In article      
 
[45]  Odhiambo, N.M, Financial depth, savings and economic growth in Kenya: a dynamic casual relationship. Economic Model, 2008, 254, 704-713.
In article      CrossRef
 
[46]  Odhiambo, N.M, Finance-investment-growth nexus in South Africa: an ARDL bounds testing procedure. Econ Change Restruct, 2010, 43, 205-219.
In article      CrossRef
 
[47]  Pesaran, M.H, General Diagnostic Tests for Cross Section Dependence in Panels. CESifo Working Paper 1229; IZA Discussion Paper, 2004, 1240.
In article      
 
[48]  Pesaran, M.H., Ullah, A., Yamagata, T, A bias-adjusted LM test of error cross section independenc. Econometrics Journal, 2008, 11, 105-127.
In article      CrossRef
 
[49]  Rajan, R., Zingales, L, Financial dependence and growth. American Economic Review, 1998, 883, 559-586.
In article      
 
[50]  Rousseau, PL., Wachtel, P, What is happening to the impact of financial deepening on economic growth? Economic Inquiry, 2011, 491, 276-288.
In article      CrossRef
 
[51]  Rousseau, P.L., Vuthipadadorn, D, Finance, investment and growth: time series evidence from 10 Asian Economies. Journal of Macroeconomics, 2005, 27, 87-106.
In article      CrossRef
 
[52]  Sarafidis, V., Robertson, D, On the impact of error cross-sectional dependence in short dynamic panel estimation. Econometrics Journal, 2009, 12, 62-81.
In article      CrossRef
 
[53]  Schumpeter, J.A, The theory of economic development. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA. 1911.
In article      
 
[54]  Schumpeter, J. A, Theorie der Wirtschaftlichen Entwickiung [The theory of economic development]. Leipzig: Dunker& Humblot, 1912; translated by Redvers Opie. Cambridge, MA: Harvard U. Press. 1934.
In article      
 
[55]  Shaw, E. S, Financial Deepening in Economic Development. Oxford University Press, New York. 1973.
In article      
 
[56]  Tekin, R.B, Economic growth, exports and foreign direct investment in Least Developed Countries: A panel Granger causality analysis, Economic Modelling, 2012.
In article      CrossRef
 
[57]  Wachtel, P, How Much Do We Really Know about Growth and Finance? Economic Review, 2003, 88, 33-48.
In article      
 
[58]  Williamson, O.E, The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. New York: Free Press. 1985.
In article      
 
[59]  Wood, A, Financial development and economic growth in Barbados, causal evidence. Savings and Development, 1993, 174, 379-390.
In article      
 
[60]  Zang, H., Kim, Y.C, Does financial development precede growth? Robinson and Lucas might be right. Applied Economics Letters, 2007, 14, 15-19.
In article      CrossRef
 
[61]  Zellner, A, An efficient method of estimating seemingly unrelated regressions and tests for aggregation bias. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 1962, 57, 348-368.
In article      CrossRef
 

Appendix: Data and Sources

BANK: The number of Banks and branches are counted from the corresponding editions of the BANKERS' ALMANAC AND YEARBOOK, London: Thomas Skinner; labor force data (for normalization) are from ILO and included in the PENN WORLD TABLES.

FIN/PIB: The financial system's share of GDP is computed from various issues of the UN NATIONAL ACCOUNT STATISTICS, New York, referring to 'finance, insurance and business services'.

FINPER: The share of labor employed in the financial system is taken from various issues the ILO YEARBOOK OF LABOUR STATISTICS, Geneva. The corresponding ISIC-2 ('international standard industrial classification of all economic activities', 1968) classification is 'majordivision 8' (financial institutions, insurance, real estate and business services)

Notes




1These countries have been distributed on the basis of per capita GDP in 1995 :The medium-income (between 1000 and 10000 $US in 1995).

2Centrally planned economies were characterized by the dominance of large enterprises, while SMEs hardly existed.

3See Demirgüç-Kunt and Levine (1999) and Beck et al.,(2000).

  • CiteULikeCiteULike
  • MendeleyMendeley
  • StumbleUponStumbleUpon
  • Add to DeliciousDelicious
  • FacebookFacebook
  • TwitterTwitter
  • LinkedInLinkedIn